Aggregation problem

An aggregate in economics is a summary measure describing a market or economy. The aggregation problem refers to the difficulty of treating an empirical or theoretical aggregate as if it reacted like a less-aggregated measure, say, about behavior of an individual agent as described in general microeconomic theory.[1] Examples of aggregates in micro- and macroeconomics relative to less aggregated counterparts are:

Standard theory uses simple assumptions to derive general, and commonly accepted, results such as the law of demand to explain market behavior. An example is the abstraction of a composite good. It considers the price of one good changing proportionately to the composite good, that is, all other goods. If this assumption is violated and the agents are subject to aggregated utility functions, restrictions on the latter are necessary to yield the law of demand. The aggregation problem emphasizes:

Franklin Fisher notes that this has not dissuaded macroeconomists from continuing to use such concepts.[2]

Aggregate consumer demand curve

The aggregate consumer demand curve is the summation of the individual consumer demand curves. The aggregation process preserves only two characteristics of individual consumer preference theory—continuity and homogeneity. Aggregation introduces three additional non-price determinants of demand:

Thus if the population of consumers increases, ceteris paribus the demand curve will shift out; if the proportion of consumers with a strong preference for a good increases, ceteris paribus the demand for that good will change. Finally, if the distribution of income changes in favor of consumers who prefer the good in question, the demand will shift out. It is important to remember that factors that affect individual demand can also affect aggregate demand. However, net effects must be considered.

Difficulties with aggregation

Independence assumption

First, to sum the demand functions without other strong assumptions it must be assumed that they are independent; that is that one consumer's demand decisions are not influenced by the decisions of another consumer.[3] For example, A is asked how many pairs of shoes he would buy at a certain price. A says at that price I would be willing and able to buy two pairs of shoes. B is asked the same question and says four pairs. Questioner goes back to A and says B is willing to buy four pairs of shoes, what do you think about that? A says if B has any interest in those shoes then I have none. Or A, not to be outdone by B, says "then I'll buy five pairs". And on and on. This problem can be eliminated by assuming that the consumers' tastes are fixed in the short run. This assumption can be expressed as assuming that each consumer is an independent idiosyncratic decision maker.

No interesting properties

This second problem is more serious. As David M. Kreps notes, “total demand will shift about as a function of how individual incomes are distributed even holding total (societal) income fixed. So it makes no sense to speak of aggregate demand as a function of price and societal income".[4] Since any change in relative price affects a redistribution of real income, there is a separate demand curve for every relative price. Kreps continues, "So what can we say about aggregate demand based on the hypothesis that individuals are preference/utility maximizers? Unless we are able to make strong assumptions about the distribution of preferences or income throughout the economy (everyone has the same homothetic preferences for example) there is little we can say”.[5] The strong assumptions are that everyone has the same tastes and that each person’s taste remain the same as income changes so additional income is spent in exactly the same way as previously.

Steve Keen notes that the first assumption amounts to assuming that there is a single consumer, and the second that there is a single good. Keen further states that because of the aggregation problem one cannot draw conclusions about social welfare, there is no invisible hand and Adam Smith was wrong.[6]

Microeconomist Hal Varian reached a more muted conclusion: "The aggregate demand function will in general possess no interesting properties".[7] However, Varian continued: "the neoclassical theory of the consumer places no restriction on aggregate behavior in general".[8] This means the preference conditions (with the possible exception of continuity) simply do not apply to the aggregate function.

See also

Notes

  1. Franklin M. Fisher (1987). "aggregation problem," The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, v. 1, p. 54. [Pp. 53-55.]
  2. Franklin M. Fisher (1987). "aggregation problem," The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, v. 1, p. 55.
  3. Besanko and Braeutigam, (2005) p. 169.
  4. Kreps (1990) p. 63.
  5. Kreps (1990) p. 63.
  6. Keen, Steve (2001). Debunking Economics.
  7. Varian (1992) p. 153.
  8. Varian (1992) p. 153.

References

This article is issued from Wikipedia - version of the Saturday, September 19, 2015. The text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution/Share Alike but additional terms may apply for the media files.