Artyom Shneyerov
Artyom Shneyerov | |
---|---|
Born |
October 20, 1968 St. Petersburg, Russia |
Residence | Canada |
Nationality | Canadian |
Fields | Economist |
Institutions | Concordia University (Montreal, Canada) |
Alma mater |
Northwestern University(Ph.D.) Vanderbilt University(M.A.) St. Petersburg Polytechnical University(B.S.) |
Known for | Game theory, Industrial organization, Econometrics |
Artyom Shneyerov is a microeconomist working at Concordia University in Montreal, Canada. He is also an Associate Editor of the International Journal of Industrial Organization.[1] His current research is in the fields of Game theory, Industrial organization and applied Econometrics. His list of contributions to these and other areas of economics includes the following:
- In his paper "An empirical study of auction revenue rankings: the case of municipal bonds",[2] he introduced an approach for the estimation of counterfactual revenues in a common value auction without the need to identify model primitives. He showed that for any given reserve price, equilibrium bids from first-price auctions can be used to identify the expected revenues in Vickrey auction with the same reserve price. In addition, he derived an explicit bound on expected revenue for English auctions. His approach is based on the revenue ranking theorem of Milgrom and Weber.[3] He has applied these results to municipal bond auctions in California. This paper is discussed in a handbook of industrial organization.[4]
- Jointly with Mark Satterthwaite,[5] and his former student Adam Chi Leung Wong, obtained a number of results about the structure of equilibria of dynamic matching and bargaining games and their convergence to perfect competition .[6][7][8] Some of these results are discussed in Bergemann and Balat (2008),[9] the lecture notes of a graduate economics course at Yale University. These games are often used to provide a foundation for the perfect competition hypothesis, one of the basic concepts in economics. They are also used frequently in search models of labor economics.[10] Most dynamic matching and bargaining models in the previous literature assumed full information.[11][12] This means that in a given meeting, the buyer knows the minimum the seller is willing to accept for the item, and the seller knows the maximum the buyer is willing to pay. This assumption is often violated in reality. Satterthwaite and Shneyerov have shown that the dynamic matching and bargaining market is nevertheless approximately competitive as the time between matches becomes progressively smaller.
- Has also done early work on the measurement of income inequality.[13][14] In "Path Independent Inequality Measures", he and James Foster introduced inequality measures that are decomposable into within and between group components. These measures have been recently applied more broadly than income inequality, e.g. to selection into and across lending contracts in Thailand.[15]
References
- ↑ The International Journal of Industrial Organization
- ↑ Shneyerov, Artyom (December 0335). "An empirical study of auction revenue rankings: the case of municipal bonds". The RAND Journal of Economics 37 (4): 1005–1022. doi:10.1111/j.1756-2171.2006.tb00068.x. Retrieved 2008-04-14.
- ↑ Milgrom, Paul R.; Robert J. Weber (September 1982). "A Theory of Auctions and Competitive Bidding". Econometrica (The Econometric Society) 50 (5): 1089–1122. doi:10.2307/1911865. ISSN 0012-9682. JSTOR 1911865.
- ↑ Hendricks, Ken; Robert H. Porter (2007). "An Empirical Perspective on Auctions". Handbook of Industrial Organization 3. Elsevier. pp. 2073–2143. Retrieved 2008-04-14.
- ↑ The author of Gibbard–Satterthwaite theorem and Myerson-Satterthwaite theorem
- ↑ Satterthwaite, Mark; Artyom Shneyerov (2007-01-01). "Dynamic Matching, Two-Sided Incomplete Information, and Participation Costs: Existence and Convergence to Perfect Competition". Econometrica 75 (1): 155–200. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0262.2007.00735.x. Retrieved 2008-04-14.
- ↑ Satterthwaite, Mark; Artyom Shneyerov (July 2008). "Convergence to perfect competition of a dynamic matching and bargaining market with two-sided incomplete information and exogenous exit rate". Games and Economic Behavior 63 (2): 435–467. doi:10.1016/j.geb.2008.04.014. Retrieved 2008-08-21.
- ↑ Shneyerov, Artyom; Adam Chi Leung Wong (2009). "Bilateral matching and bargaining with private information". Games and Economic Behavior 68 (2): 748. doi:10.1016/j.geb.2009.10.005. Retrieved 2009-11-09.
- ↑ Dirk Bergemann and Jorge Balat, Advanced Microeconomic Theory 521B Lecture Notes
- ↑ Richard Rogerson, Richard; Robert Shimer; Randall Wright (2005). "Search-Theoretic Models of the Labor Market: A Survey". Journal of Economic Literature. Journal of Economic Literature 43 (4): 959–988. doi:10.1257/002205105775362014. Retrieved 2008-04-14.
- ↑ Rubinstein, Ariel; Asher Wolinsky (1990). "Decentralized Trading, Strategic Behaviour and the Walrasian Outcome". Review of Economic Studies. Review of Economic Studies 57 (1): 63–78. doi:10.2307/2297543. JSTOR 2297543. Retrieved 2008-04-16.
- ↑ Gale, Douglas (1987). "Limit theorems for markets with sequential bargaining". Journal of Economic Theory. Journal of Economic Theory 43 (1): 20–54. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(87)90114-1. Retrieved 2008-04-16.
- ↑ Foster, James E.; Artyom A. Shneyerov (April 2000). "Path Independent Inequality Measures". Journal of Economic Theory 91 (2): 199–222. doi:10.1006/jeth.1999.2565. Retrieved 2008-04-14.
- ↑ Foster, James E.; Artyom A. Shneyerov (1999-07-18). "A general class of additively decomposable inequality measures". Economic Theory 14 (1): 89–111. doi:10.1007/s001990050283.
- ↑ Ahlin, Christian; Robert M. Townsend (February 2007). "Selection into and across credit contracts: Theory and field research". Journal of Econometrics 136 (2): 665–698. doi:10.1016/j.jeconom.2005.11.013. Retrieved 2008-04-14.
External links
This article is issued from Wikipedia - version of the Thursday, April 28, 2016. The text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution/Share Alike but additional terms may apply for the media files.