Constant elasticity of substitution

Constant elasticity of substitution (CES), in economics, is a property of some production functions and utility functions.

Specifically, it arises in a particular type of aggregator function which combines two or more types of consumption, or two or more types of productive inputs into an aggregate quantity. This aggregator function exhibits constant elasticity of substitution.

CES production function

The CES production function is a neoclassical production function that displays constant elasticity of substitution. In other words, the production technology has a constant percentage change in factor (e.g. labour and capital) proportions due to a percentage change in marginal rate of technical substitution. The two factor (capital, labor) CES production function introduced by Solow,[1] and later made popular by Arrow, Chenery, Minhas, and Solow is:[2][3][4]

 Q = F \cdot \left(a \cdot K^r+(1-a) \cdot L^r\right)^{\frac{1}{r}}

where

As its name suggests, the CES production function exhibits constant elasticity of substitution between capital and labor. Leontief, linear and Cobb–Douglas functions are special cases of the CES production function. That is,

The general form of the CES production function, with n inputs, is:[5]

 Q = F \cdot \left[\sum_{i=1}^n a_{i}X_{i}^{r}\ \right]^{\frac{1}{r}}

where

Extending the CES (Solow) form to accommodate multiple factors of production creates some problems, however. There is no completely general way to do this. Uzawa showed the only possible n-factor production functions (n>2) with constant partial elasticities of substitution require either that all elasticities between pairs of factors be identical, or if any differ, these all must equal each other and all remaining elasticities must be unity.[6] This is true for any production function. This means the use of the CES form for more than 2 factors will generally mean that there is not constant elasticity of substitution among all factors.

Nested CES functions are commonly found in partial equilibrium and general equilibrium models. Different nests (levels) allow for the introduction of the appropriate elasticity of substitution.

CES utility function

The same functional form arises as a utility function in consumer theory. For example, if there exist n types of consumption goods x_i, then aggregate consumption X could be defined using the CES aggregator:

 X = \left[\sum_{i=1}^n a_{i}^{\frac{1}{s}}x_{i}^{\frac{(s-1)}{s}}\ \right]^{\frac{s}{(s-1)}}

Here again, the coefficients a_i are share parameters, and s is the elasticity of substitution. Therefore the consumption goods c_i are perfect substitutes when s approaches infinity and perfect complements when s approaches zero. The CES aggregator is also sometimes called the Armington aggregator, which was discussed by Armington (1969).[7]

CES utility functions are a special case of homothetic preferences.

The following is an example of a CES utility function for two goods, x and y, with equal shares:[8]:112

u(x,y) =(x^r + y^r)^{1/r}

The expenditure function in this case is:

e(p_x,p_y,u) =(p_x^r + p_y^r)^{1/r} \cdot u

The indirect utility function is its inverse:

v(p_x,p_y,I) =(p_x^r + p_y^r)^{-1/r} \cdot I

The demand functions are:

x(p_x,p_y,I) = \frac{p_x^{r-1}}{p_x^r + p_y^r}\cdot I

A CES utility function is one of the cases considered by Dixit and Stiglitz in their study of optimal product diversity in a context of monopolistic competition.[9]

A CES indirect utility function is considered by Baltas (2001) to derive a utility-consistent brand demand system. The brand-level model is subsequently extended to allow the joint determination of brand demand and category expenditure. Category demand is determined endogenously by a multi-category CES indirect utility function encapsulating consumer preferences over brands and product categories in a large simultaneous system. It is also shown that CES preferences are self-dual and that primal and dual CES preferences yield systems of indifference curves that may exhibit any degree of convexity.[10]

Note the difference between CES utility and isoelastic utility: the former is an ordinal utility function that represents preferences on sure bundles, while the latter is a cardinal utility function that represents preferences on lotteries.

References

  1. Solow, R.M (1956). "A contribution to the theory of economic growth". The Quarterly Journal of Economics 70: 65–94. doi:10.2307/1884513.
  2. Arrow, K. J.; Chenery, H. B.; Minhas, B. S.; Solow, R. M. (1961). "Capital-labor substitution and economic efficiency". Review of Economics and Statistics (The MIT Press) 43 (3): 225–250. doi:10.2307/1927286. JSTOR 1927286.
  3. Jorgensen, Dale W. (2000). Econometrics, vol. 1: Econometric Modelling of Producer Behavior. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. p. 2. ISBN 0-262-10082-7.
  4. Klump, R; McAdam, P; Willman, A. (2007). "Factor Substitution and Factor Augmenting Technical Progress in the US: A Normalized Supply-Side System Approach". Review of Economics and Statistics (The MIT Press) 89 (1): 183–192. doi:10.1162/rest.89.1.183.
  5. http://www.econ.ucsb.edu/~tedb/Courses/GraduateTheoryUCSB/elasticity%20of%20substitutionrevised.tex.pdf
  6. Uzawa, H (1962). "Production functions with constant elasticities of substitution". Review of Economic Studies 9: 291–299.
  7. Armington, P. S. (1969). "A theory of demand for products distinguished by place of production". IMF Staff Papers 16: 159–178. doi:10.2307/3866403.
  8. Varian, Hal (1992). Microeconomic Analysis (Third ed.). New York: Norton. ISBN 0393957357.
  9. Dixit, Avinash; Stiglitz, Joseph (1977). "Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity". American Economic Review 67 (3): 297–308. JSTOR 1831401.
  10. Baltas, George (2001). "Utility-Consistent Brand Demand Systems with Endogenous Category Consumption: Principles and Marketing Applications". Decision Sciences 32 (3): 399–421. doi:10.1111/j.1540-5915.2001.tb00965.x.

External links

This article is issued from Wikipedia - version of the Saturday, January 16, 2016. The text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution/Share Alike but additional terms may apply for the media files.