Capital structure substitution theory

In finance, the capital structure substitution theory (CSS)[1] describes the relationship between earnings, stock price and capital structure of public companies. The CSS theory hypothesizes that managements of public companies manipulate capital structure such that earnings per share (EPS) are maximized. Managements have an incentive to do so because shareholders and analysts value EPS growth. The theory is used to explain trends in capital structure, stock market valuation, dividend policy, the monetary transmission mechanism, and stock volatility, and provides an alternative to the Modigliani–Miller theorem that has limited descriptive validity in real markets. The CSS theory is only applicable in markets where share repurchases are allowed. Investors can use the CSS theory to identify undervalued stocks.[2][3]

The formula

The CSS theory assumes that company managements can freely change the capital structure of the company – substituting bonds for stock or vice versa – on a day-to-day basis and in small denominations without paying transaction costs. Companies can decide to buy back one single share for the current market price P and finance this by issuing one extra corporate bond with face value P or do the reverse. In mathematical terms these substitutions are defined as

test1
CSS equilibrium conditions: (1) companies fulfilling the equilibrium condition are found on B-B", (2) companies cannot issue debt with interest rates below 'Aaa' rated bonds on line A-A", (3) high valued companies with E/P<R*[1-T] are not expected to hold long term debt, pay no dividends and are found on line A-B.

\left[\frac{\partial D}{\partial n}\right] _{\text{x,t}} = -P_{\text{x,t}}

where D is the corporate debt and n the number of shares of company x at time t. The negative sign indicates that a reduction of the number of shares n leads to a larger debt D and vice versa. The earnings-per-share change when one share with price P is repurchased and one bond with face value P is issued:

  1. The earnings that were ‘allocated’ to the one share that was repurchased are redistributed over the remaining outstanding shares, causing an increase in earnings per share of: E/n
  2. The earnings are reduced by the additional interest payments on the extra bond. As interest payments are tax-deductible the real reduction in earnings is obtained by multiplying with the tax shield. The additional interest payments thus reduce the EPS by: P\cdot R\cdot [1-T]/n

Combining these two effects, the marginal change in EPS as function of the total number of outstanding shares becomes:

\left[\frac{\partial E}{\partial n}\right] _{\text{x,t}} = -\frac{E_{\text{x,t}}}{n}+\frac{P_{\text{x,t}}\ R_{\text{x,t}}\ [1-T]}{n}

where

EPS is maximized when substituting one more share for one bond or vice versa leads to no marginal change in EPS or:

\frac{E_{\text{x,t}}}{P_{\text{x,t}}}=R_{\text{x,t}}\ [1-T]

This equilibrium condition is the central result of the CCS theory, linking stock prices to interest rates on corporate bonds.

Capital structure

The two main capital structure theories as taught in corporate finance textbooks are the Pecking order theory and the Trade-off theory. The two theories make some contradicting predictions and for example Fama and French conclude:[4] "In sum, we identify one scar on the tradeoff model (the negative relation between leverage and profitability), one deep wound on the pecking order (the large equity issues of small low-leverage growth firms)...". The capital structure substitution theory has the potential to close these gaps. It predicts a negative relation between leverage and valuation (=reverse of earnings yield) which in turn can be linked to profitability. But it also predicts that high valued small growth firms will avoid the use of debt as especially for these companies the cost of borrowing (R_{\text{x,t}} ) is higher than for large companies, which in turn has a negative effect on their EPS. This is consistent with the finding that "…firms with higher current stock prices (relative to their past stock prices, book values or earnings) are more likely to issue equity rather than debt and repurchase debt rather than equity".[5]

Asset pricing

The equilibrium condition can be easily rearranged to an asset pricing formula:

P_{\text{x,t}}=\frac{E_{\text{x,t}}}{R_{\text{x,t}}[1-T]}

The CSS theory suggests that company share prices are not set by shareholders but by bondholders. As a result of active repurchasing or issuing of shares by company managements, equilibrium pricing is no longer a result of balancing shareholder demand and supply. In a way the CSS theory turns asset pricing upside-down, with bondholders setting share prices and shareholders determining company leverage. The asset pricing formula only applies to debt-holding companies. Some companies are offering stock screeners based on the CSS theory.

Fed model equilibrium

In the US, a positive relationship between the average earnings yield of the S&P 500 index and government bond yields has been present over the last several decades. This relationship has become popular as the Fed model and states in its strongest form an equality between the one year forward looking E/P ratio or earnings yield and the 10-year government bond yield. The CSS equilibrium condition suggests that the Fed model is misspecified: the S&P 500 earnings yield is not in equilibrium with the government bond yield but with the average after-tax interest rate on corporate bonds. The CSS theory suggests that the Fed equilibrium was only observable after 1982, the year in which the United States Securities and Exchange Commission allowed open-market repurchases of shares.[6]

Dividend policy

It can be shown that repurchasing has a disadvantage over dividends for companies with a debt-equity ratio above

\frac{D}{E_{\text{q}}}>\frac{1-T_{\text{C}}}{1-T_{\text{D}}}-1
Under the assumptions described above, low valued, high leveraged companies with limited investment opportunities and a high profitability are expected to use dividends as the preferred means to distribute cash.

Monetary policy

An unanticipated 25-basis-point cut in the federal funds rate target is associated with a 1% increase in broad stock indexes in the US.[7] The CSS theory suggests that the monetary policy transmission mechanism is indirect but straightforward: a change in the federal funds rate affects the corporate bond market which in turn affects asset prices through the equilibrium condition.

Beta

The CSS equilibrium condition can be used to deduct a relationship for the beta of a company x at time t:

Beta_{\text{x,t}}=\overline{R_{\text{t}}}\cdot\left[\frac{P}{E}\right]_{\text{x,t}}\cdot[1-T]

where \overline{R_{\text{t}}} is the market average interest rate on corporate bonds. The CSS theory predicts that companies with a low valuation and high leverage will have a low beta. This is counter-intuitive as traditional finance theory links leverage to risk, and risk to high beta.

Assumptions

See also

References

  1. Timmer, Jan (2011). "Understanding the Fed Model, Capital Structure, and then Some".
  2. Godwin, Steve (April 25, 2015). Protecting Your Money in the Stock Market: It’s a Herd Game!. Xlibris. ISBN 978-1503558427.
  3. Zürcher, Ulrik Årdal (2014). "The Effect of Interest Rates on Equity Markets That Allows Share Repurchases" (PDF).
  4. Fama, E.F.; French, K.R. (December 2002). "Testing Tradeoff and Pecking Order Predictions About Dividends and Debt". Review of Financial Studies 15: 1–33. doi:10.1093/rfs/15.1.1. SSRN 199431.
  5. Hovakimian, A.; Opler, T.; Titman, S. (2001). "The Debt-Equity Choice". Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 36: 1–24. doi:10.2307/2676195.
  6. Grullon, G.; Michaely, R. (August 2002). "Dividends, share repurchase, and the substitution hypothesis" (PDF). Journal of Finance LVII (4): 1649–1684. doi:10.1111/1540-6261.00474.
  7. Bernanke, B.S.; Kuttner, K.N. (June 2005). "What Explains the Stock Market’s Reaction to Federal Reserve Policy?" (PDF). Journal of Finance LX: 1221–1257. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.2005.00760.x.

External links

This article is issued from Wikipedia - version of the Thursday, May 05, 2016. The text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution/Share Alike but additional terms may apply for the media files.