DNSS point

DNSS points, also known as Skiba points, arise in optimal control problems that exhibit multiple optimal solutions. A DNSS point-named alphabetically after Deckert and Nishimura,[1] Sethi,[2][3] and Skiba[4]-is an indifference point in an optimal control problem such that starting from such a point, the problem has more than one different optimal solutions. A good discussion of such points can be found in Grass et al.[5]

Definition

Of particular interest here are discounted infinite horizon optimal control problems that are autonomous.[6] These problems can be formulated as


\max_{u(t)\in \Omega}\int_0^{\infty} e^{-\rho t} \varphi\left(x(t), u(t)\right)dt

s.t.


\dot{x}(t) = f\left(x(t), u(t)\right), x(0) = x_{0},

where \rho > 0 is the discount rate, x(t) and u(t) are the state and control variables, respectively, at time t, functions \varphi and f are assumed to be continuously differentiable with respect to their arguments and they do not depend explicitly on time t, and \Omega is the set of feasible controls and it also is explicitly independent of time t. Furthermore, it is assumed that the integral converges for any admissible solution \left(x(.), u(.)\right). In such a problem with one-dimensional state variable x, the initial state x_{0} is called a DNSS point if the system starting from it exhibits multiple optimal solutions or equilibria. Thus, at least in the neighborhood of x_0, the system moves to one equilibrium for x > x_0 and to another for x < x_0. In this sense, x_0 is an indifference point from which the system could move to either of the two equilibria.

For two-dimensional optimal control problems, Grass et al.[5] and Zeiler et al.[7] present examples that exhibit DNSS curves.

Some references on the application of DNSS points are Caulkins et al.[8] and Zeiler et al.[9]

History

Suresh P. Sethi identified such indifference points for the first time in 1977.[2] Further, Skiba,[4] Sethi,[3] and Deckert and Nishimura[1] explored these indifference points in economic models. The term DNSS (Deckert, Nishimura, Sethi, Skiba) points, introduced by Grass et al.,[5] recognizes (alphabetically) the contributions of these authors.

These indifference points have been referred to earlier as Skiba points or DNS points in the literature.[5]

Example

A simple problem exhibiting this behavior is given by \varphi\left(x,u\right) =xu, f\left(x,u\right) = -x + u, and \Omega = \left[-1, 1\right]. It is shown in Grass et al.[5] that x_{0} = 0 is a DNSS point for this problem because the optimal path x(t) can be either \left(1-e^{-t}\right) or \left(-1+e^{-t}\right). Note that for x_{0} < 0, the optimal path is x(t) = -1 + e^{-t\left(x_{0}+1 \right)} and for x_{0} > 0, the optimal path is x(t) = 1 + e^{-t\left(x_{0}-1 \right)}.

Extensions

For further details and extensions, the reader is referred to Grass et al.[5]

References

  1. 1 2 Deckert, D.W.; Nishimura, K. (1983). "A Complete Characterization of Optimal Growth Paths in an Aggregated Model with Nonconcave Production Function". Journal of Economic Theory 31 (2): 332–354. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(83)90081-9.
  2. 1 2 Sethi, S.P. (1977). "Nearest Feasible Paths in Optimal Control Problems: Theory, Examples, and Counterexamples". Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications 23 (4): 563–579. doi:10.1007/BF00933297.
  3. 1 2 Sethi, S.P. (1979). "Optimal Advertising Policy with the Contagion Model". Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications 29 (4): 615–627. doi:10.1007/BF00934454.
  4. 1 2 Skiba, A.K. (1978). "Optimal Growth with a Convex-Concave Production Function". Econometrica 46 (3): 527–539. doi:10.2307/1914229. JSTOR 1914229.
  5. 1 2 3 4 5 6 Grass, D., Caulkins, J.P., Feichtinger, G., Tragler, G., Behrens, D.A. (2008). Optimal Control of Nonlinear Processes: With Applications in Drugs, Corruption, and Terror. Springer. ISBN 978-3-540-77646-8.
  6. Sethi, S.P. and Thompson, G.L. (2000). Optimal Control Theory: Applications to Management Science and Economics. Second Edition. Springer. ISBN 0-387-28092-8 and ISBN 0-7923-8608-6. Slides are available at http://www.utdallas.edu/~sethi/OPRE7320presentation.html
  7. Zeiler, I., Caulkins, J., Grass, D., Tragler, G. (2009). Keeping Options Open: An Optimal Control Model with Trajectories that Reach a DNSS Point in Positive Time. SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization, Vol. 48, No. 6, pp. 3698-3707.| doi =10.1137/080719741 |
  8. Caulkins, J. P.; Feichtinger, G.; Grass, D.; Tragler, G. (2009). "Optimal control of terrorism and global reputation: A case study with novel threshold behavior". Operations Research Letters 37 (6): 387–391. doi:10.1016/j.orl.2009.07.003.
  9. I. Zeiler, J. P. Caulkins, and G. Tragler. When Two Become One: Optimal Control of Interacting Drug. Working paper, Vienna University of Technology, Vienna, Austria
This article is issued from Wikipedia - version of the Thursday, January 14, 2016. The text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution/Share Alike but additional terms may apply for the media files.