Intra-household bargaining

Intra-household bargaining refers to negotiations that occur between members of a household in order to arrive at decisions regarding the household unit, like whether to spend or save, whether to study or work.

Bargaining is traditionally defined in economic terms of negotiating conditions of a purchase or contract and is sometimes used in place of direct monetary exchange.[1] Bargaining process within a family is one of the important aspects of family economics. Bargaining also plays a role in the functioning and decision making of households, where agreements and decisions do not often have direct monetary values and affect various members of the household.[2]

Game theory

Within the household unit and in the mathematical study of game theory, scholars have defined two distinct types of bargaining: cooperative and non-cooperative.[3] In cooperative bargaining models (also called collaborative decision making), the outcomes of negotiations are more equally beneficial to all members of the household, and have therefore been considered a more “natural” means of analyzing the family unit in comparison to non-cooperative models.[4] In non-cooperative bargaining models (also called unitary decision making), personal interests motivate individuals within the household rather than the desire to work in a collaborative manner and maximize the benefit of all household members.[4][5]

Household dynamics

The household is traditionally described as a single economic unit that “works as a group for its own good”, meaning all members of the household contribute in an altruistic manner towards the benefit and functioning of the entire household.[6] The household is "the basic residential unit in which economic production, consumption, inheritance, child rearing, and shelter are organized and carried out".[7] Though it is not always synonymous with family, in the case of intra-household bargaining, in which members of the household are considered to be one unit, the household is generally synonymous.[8]

Because a household is composed of various individuals, conflicts of interest arise. These conflicts of interest make bargaining a necessary fact of household life and create a household environment that is not universally governed by altruism.[2][9] These conflicts of interest have the potential to create a spectrum of intra-household dynamics, ranging from a non-cooperative to a cooperative household (which is directly reflective of game theoretic bargaining models). In the non-cooperative model, each household member acts in order to maximize his or her own utility; in the cooperative model, households act as a unit to “maximize the welfare of their members” (described above as altruism).[9]

Bargaining power

Bargaining power is “the relative capacity of each of the parties to a negotiation or dispute to compel or secure agreements on its own terms”.[1] In other words, “if both parties are on equal footing in a debate, then they will have equal bargaining power”, and, conversely, if one party has an advantageous position in the debate, the parties have unequal bargaining power.

More specifically, what determines the equality or inequality of bargaining power is the relative fallback positions or “threat points” of the individuals in the bargaining process; that is, which bargainer has more to lose (economically, socially, etc.)?[2] In the context of intra-household bargaining, an individual’s bargaining power and fallback position are defined by one’s ability to survive and thrive outside the family.[10]

Factors that determine fallback positions

Individual assets

The access one has to individual assets, both economic (such as property, land, wealth, or earning ability) and personal (such as labor), determines fallback position because it is directly linked to one’s capability of surviving outside the household.[11]

Extra-household parameters

The structural support, whether institutional or societal, an individual has outside of the household determines how capable one would be of surviving outside the household.

Inequalities in bargaining power

Unequal access to strong fallback positions creates a situation in which different individuals within the household have more or less bargaining power, and therefore have more or less influence over household decision-making. When considering the factors that determine fallback position in intra-household bargaining and what populations have access to positive fallback positions, Bina Agarwal’s research in rural South Asian communities shows that in said communities women have unequal access to strong bargaining power and their interests are not reflected in household decisions.[2][21][22]

Individual assets

In South Asian societies land is one of the most valuable individual assets that can increase an individual’s bargaining power, yet it is more uncommon and difficult for women to own land than men for a number of reasons: inheritance laws that allow women to inherit land are not strongly enforced, in order to own land individuals must obtain a certain level of education, which women have traditionally not had access to, and owning land and enforcing laws depends upon one’s “economic and physical access to legal machinery” as well as access to government officials.[15][22] Due to the unequal gender rights to land ownership, South Asian women are less capable of providing income to the household which lessens their bargaining power in the household.[2][23][21]

Social norms and gender perceptions

Due to the traditional role of women in South Asia as caretakers in the household rather than workers bringing an income to the household, women are not socially perceived as deserving of more opportunities because worth correlates with wealth and not the quality or amount of work one has done.[9][24]

See also

References

  1. 1 2 "Bargain (definition)". Merriam-Webster, Inc. Retrieved 2011.
  2. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Agarwal, Bina (1997). ""Bargaining" and gender relations: within and beyond the household". Feminist Economics (Taylor and Francis) 3 (1): 1–51. doi:10.1080/135457097338799.
  3. Katz, Elizabeth G (1996). "Intra-household economics: neo-classical synthesis or feminist-institutional challenge?". Department of Economics, Barnard College, USA (Mimeo).
  4. 1 2 Fortin, Bernard; Lacroix, Guy (July 1997). "A test of the unitary and collective models of household labour supply". The Economic Journal (Wiley Online) 107 (443): 933–955. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0297.1997.tb00001.x.
  5. Donni, Olivier; Chiappori, Pierre-André (2011), "Nonunitary models of household behavior: a survey of the literature", in Molina, José A, Household economic behaviors, New York: Springer, pp. 1–40, ISBN 9781441994318
  6. Haviland, William (2011). Cultural anthropology: the human challenge. Belmont, CA: Wadsworth/Cengage Learning. p. 184. ISBN 9780495810827.
  7. Haviland, William (2011). Cultural anthropology: the human challenge. Belmont, CA: Wadsworth/Cengage Learning. p. 219. ISBN 9780495810827.
  8. Agarwal, Bina (1997). ""Bargaining" and gender relations: within and beyond the household". Feminist Economics (Taylor and Francis) 3 (1): 39. doi:10.1080/135457097338799.
  9. 1 2 3 Folbre, Nancy (February 1986). "Hearts and spades: paradigms of household economics". World Development (Elsevier) 14 (2): 245–255. doi:10.1016/0305-750X(86)90056-2.
  10. 1 2 Agarwal, Bina (1997). ""Bargaining" and gender relations: within and beyond the household". Feminist Economics (Taylor and Francis) 3 (1): 9. doi:10.1080/135457097338799.
  11. Sen, Amartya (1982). Poverty and famines: an essay on entitlement and deprivation. Oxford New York: Clarendon Press Oxford University Press. ISBN 9780198284635.
  12. Agarwal, Bina (1999), "Social security and the family: coping with seasonality and calamity in rural India", in Sen, Amartya; Drèze, Jean; Hills, John; et al., Social security in developing countries, New Dehli London: Oxford University Press, pp. 171–246, ISBN 9780195651522
  13. Uchino, Bert N; Uno, Darcy; Holt-Lunstad, Julianne (October 1999). "Social support, physiological processes, and health". Current Directions in Psychological Science (Sage) 8 (5): 145-148. doi:10.1111/1467-8721.00034.
  14. Agarwal, Bina (1997). ""Bargaining" and gender relations: within and beyond the household". Feminist Economics (Taylor and Francis) 3 (1): 10. doi:10.1080/135457097338799.
  15. 1 2 Agarwal, Bina (1997). ""Bargaining" and gender relations: within and beyond the household". Feminist Economics (Taylor and Francis) 3 (1): 10–11. doi:10.1080/135457097338799.
  16. Lundberg, Shelly; Pollak, Robert A (December 1993). "Separate spheres bargaining and the marriage market". Journal of Political Economy (JSTOR) 101 (6): 988–1010. doi:10.1086/261912.
  17. Abdullah, Tahrunnessa A; Zeidenstein, Sondra A (1982). Village women of Bangladesh--prospects for change: a study. Oxford Oxfordshire New York: Pergamon Press. ISBN 9780080267951.
  18. Sen, Amartya (1990), "Gender and cooperative conflicts", in Tinker, Irene, Persistent inequalities: women and world development, New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 123–148, ISBN 9780195061581
  19. Shelton, Beth Anne; John, Daphne (August 1996). "The division of household labor". Annual Review of Sociology (Annual Reviews) 22: 299-322. doi:10.1146/annurev.soc.22.1.299.
  20. Iversen, Vegard (2003). "Intra-household inequality: A challenge for the capability approach?". Feminist Economics (Taylor and Francis) 9 (2-3): 93–115. doi:10.1080/1354570032000080868.
  21. 1 2 Agarwal, Bina (1986). "Women, poverty and agricultural growth in India". The Journal of Peasant Studies (Taylor and Francis) 13 (4): 165–220. doi:10.1080/03066158608438309.
  22. 1 2 Agarwal, Bina (1994). A field of one's own: gender and land rights in South Asia. Cambridge England New York, NY, USA: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 9780521429269.
  23. Agarwal, Bina (October 1994). "Gender and command over property: a critical gap in economic analysis and policy in South Asia". World Development (Elsevier) 22 (10): 1455–1478. doi:10.1016/0305-750X(94)90031-0.
  24. Folbre, Nancy; Haddad, Lawrence; Berquó, Elza (1995). Engendering economics: new perspectives on women, work and demographic change. Washington, DC: Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics. World Bank.
This article is issued from Wikipedia - version of the Thursday, November 26, 2015. The text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution/Share Alike but additional terms may apply for the media files.