Sethi model

The Sethi model was developed by Suresh P. Sethi and describes the process of how sales evolve over time in response to advertising.[1] The rate of change in sales depend on three effects: response to advertising that acts positively on the unsold portion of the market, the loss due to forgetting or possibly due to competitive factors that act negatively on the sold portion of the market, and a random effect that can go either way.

Suresh Sethi published his paper "Deterministic and Stochastic Optimization of a Dynamic Advertising Model" in 1983.[1] The Sethi model is a modification as well as a stochastic extension of the Vidale-Wolfe advertising model.[2] The model and its competitive extensions have been used extensively in the literature.[3][4][5][6][7][8][9][10][11] Moreover, some of these extensions have been also tested empirically.[4][5][8][11]

Model

The Sethi advertising model or simply the Sethi model provides a sales-advertising dynamics in the form of the following stochastic differential equation:

 dX_t =\left(rU_t\sqrt{1-X_t} - \delta X_t\right)\,dt+\sigma(X_t)\,dz_t, \qquad X_0=x.

Where:

Explanation

The rate of change in sales depend on three effects: response to advertising that acts positively on the unsold portion of the market via r, the loss due to forgetting or possibly due to competitive factors that act negatively on the sold portion of the market via \delta, and a random effect using a diffusion or White noise term that can go either way.

Example of an optimal advertising problem

Subject to the Sethi model above with the initial market share x, consider the following objective function:

V(x) = \max_{U_t \geq 0} \;E\left[ \int_0^\infty e^{-\rho t}(\pi X_t-U_t^2)\,dt\right],

where \pi denotes the sales revenue corresponding to the total market, i.e., when x = 1, and \rho > 0 denotes the discount rate.

The function V(x) is known as the value function for this problem, and it is shown to be[12]


V(x)=\bar\lambda x+ \frac{\bar\lambda^2 r^2}{4
\rho},

where


\bar\lambda=\frac{\sqrt{(\rho+\delta)^2+r^2
\pi}-(\rho+\delta)}{r^2/2}.

The optimal control for this problem is[12]

 U^*_t = u^*(X_t)=\frac{r\bar\lambda \sqrt{1-\ X_t}}{2} = \begin{cases}
{} > \bar{u} & \text{if } X_t < \bar{x}, \\
{} = \bar{u} & \text{if } X_t = \bar{x}, \\
{} < \bar{u} & \text{if } X_t > \bar{x},
\end{cases}

where


\bar x= \frac{r^2 \bar\lambda /2}{r^2 \bar\lambda /2+\delta}

and


\bar u=\frac{r\bar\lambda \sqrt{1-\bar x}}{2}.

Extensions of the Sethi model

See also

References

  1. 1 2 3 Sethi, S. P. (1983). "Deterministic and Stochastic Optimization of a Dynamic Advertising Model". Optimal Control Application and Methods 4 (2): 179–184. doi:10.1002/oca.4660040207.
  2. Vidale, M. L.; Wolfe, H. B. (1957). "An Operations-Research Study of Sales Response to Advertising". Operations Research 5 (3): 370–381. doi:10.1287/opre.5.3.370.
  3. 1 2 3 Sorger, G. (1989). "Competitive Dynamic Advertising: A Modification of the Case Game". Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 13 (1): 55–80. doi:10.1016/0165-1889(89)90011-0.
  4. 1 2 3 Chintagunta, P. K.; Vilcassim, N. J. (1992). "An Empirical Investigation of Advertising Strategies in a Dynamic Duopoly". Management Science 38 (9): 1230–1244. doi:10.1287/mnsc.38.9.1230.
  5. 1 2 3 Chintagunta, P. K.; Jain, D. C. (1995). "Empirical Analysis of a Dynamic Duopoly Model of Competition". Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 4 (1): 109–131. doi:10.1111/j.1430-9134.1995.00109.x.
  6. 1 2 Prasad, A.; Sethi, S. P. (2004). "Competitive Advertising under Uncertainty: Stochastic Differential Game Approach". Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications 123 (1): 163–185. doi:10.1023/B:JOTA.0000043996.62867.20.
  7. 1 2 Bass, F. M.; Krishamoorthy, A.; Prasad, A.; Sethi, S. P. (2005). "Generic and Brand Advertising Strategies in a Dynamic Duopoly". Marketing Science 24 (4): 556–568. doi:10.1287/mksc.1050.0119.
  8. 1 2 3 4 Naik, P. A.; Prasad, A.; Sethi, S. P. (2008). "Building Brand Awareness in Dynamic Oligopoly Markets". Management Science 54 (1): 129–138. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1070.0755.
  9. 1 2 Erickson, G. M. (2009). "An Oligopoly Model of Dynamic Advertising Competition". European Journal of Operations Research.
  10. Prasad, A.; Sethi, S. P. (2009). "Integrated Marketing Communications in Markets with Uncertainty and Competition". Automatica 45 (3): 601–610. doi:10.1016/j.automatica.2008.09.018.
  11. 1 2 3 4 Erickson, G. M. (2009). "Advertising Competition in a Dynamic Oligopoly with Multiple Brands". Operations Research 57 (5): 1106–1113. doi:10.1287/opre.1080.0663.
  12. 1 2 Sethi, S.P., Thompson, G.L. (2000). Optimal Control Theory: Applications to Management Science and Economics. Second Edition. Springer. ISBN 0-387-28092-8 and ISBN 0-7923-8608-6, pp. 352-355. Slides are available at http://www.utdallas.edu/~sethi/OPRE7320presentation.html
  13. He, X.; Prasad, A.; Sethi, S.P. (2009). "Cooperative Advertising and Pricing in a Stochastic Supply Chain: Feedback Stackelberg Strategies". Production and Operations Management 18 (1): 78–94. doi:10.1111/j.1937-5956.2009.01006.x.
  14. He, X.; Prasad, A.; Sethi, S.P.; Gutierrez, G. (2007). "A Survey of Stackelberg Differential Game Models in Supply and Marketing Channels". Journal of Systems Science and Systems Engineering 16 (4): 385–413. doi:10.1007/s11518-007-5058-2.
  15. Sethi, S.P.; Prasad, A.; He, X. (2008). "Optimal Advertising and Pricing in a New-Product Adoption Model". Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications 139 (2): 351–360. doi:10.1007/s10957-008-9472-5.
  16. Krishnamoorthy, A., Prasad, A., Sethi, S.P. (2009). Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly. European Journal of Operations Research.
This article is issued from Wikipedia - version of the Friday, April 01, 2016. The text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution/Share Alike but additional terms may apply for the media files.