Sethi model
The Sethi model was developed by Suresh P. Sethi and describes the process of how sales evolve over time in response to advertising.[1] The rate of change in sales depend on three effects: response to advertising that acts positively on the unsold portion of the market, the loss due to forgetting or possibly due to competitive factors that act negatively on the sold portion of the market, and a random effect that can go either way.
Suresh Sethi published his paper "Deterministic and Stochastic Optimization of a Dynamic Advertising Model" in 1983.[1] The Sethi model is a modification as well as a stochastic extension of the Vidale-Wolfe advertising model.[2] The model and its competitive extensions have been used extensively in the literature.[3][4][5][6][7][8][9][10][11] Moreover, some of these extensions have been also tested empirically.[4][5][8][11]
Model
The Sethi advertising model or simply the Sethi model provides a sales-advertising dynamics in the form of the following stochastic differential equation:
- .
Where:
- is the market share at time
- is the rate of advertising at time
- is the coefficient of the effectiveness of advertising
- is the decay constant
- is the diffusion coefficient
- is the Wiener process (Standard Brownian motion); is known as White noise.
Explanation
The rate of change in sales depend on three effects: response to advertising that acts positively on the unsold portion of the market via , the loss due to forgetting or possibly due to competitive factors that act negatively on the sold portion of the market via , and a random effect using a diffusion or White noise term that can go either way.
- The coefficient is the coefficient of the effectiveness of advertising innovation.
- The coefficient is the decay constant.
- The square-root term brings in the so-called word-of-mouth effect at least at low sales levels.[1][3]
- The diffusion term brings in the random effect.
Example of an optimal advertising problem
Subject to the Sethi model above with the initial market share , consider the following objective function:
where denotes the sales revenue corresponding to the total market, i.e., when , and denotes the discount rate.
The function is known as the value function for this problem, and it is shown to be[12]
where
The optimal control for this problem is[12]
where
and
Extensions of the Sethi model
- Competitive extensions-Nash differential games[3][6][7][8][9][11]
- Empirical testing of the Sethi model and extensions[4][5][8][11]
- Stackelberg differential games [13][14]
- The Sethi durable goods model[15][16]
See also
- Bass diffusion model
- differential games
- Stochastic differential equation
- Diffusion of innovations
- Stackleberg competition
- Nash equilibrium
References
- 1 2 3 Sethi, S. P. (1983). "Deterministic and Stochastic Optimization of a Dynamic Advertising Model". Optimal Control Application and Methods 4 (2): 179–184. doi:10.1002/oca.4660040207.
- ↑ Vidale, M. L.; Wolfe, H. B. (1957). "An Operations-Research Study of Sales Response to Advertising". Operations Research 5 (3): 370–381. doi:10.1287/opre.5.3.370.
- 1 2 3 Sorger, G. (1989). "Competitive Dynamic Advertising: A Modification of the Case Game". Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 13 (1): 55–80. doi:10.1016/0165-1889(89)90011-0.
- 1 2 3 Chintagunta, P. K.; Vilcassim, N. J. (1992). "An Empirical Investigation of Advertising Strategies in a Dynamic Duopoly". Management Science 38 (9): 1230–1244. doi:10.1287/mnsc.38.9.1230.
- 1 2 3 Chintagunta, P. K.; Jain, D. C. (1995). "Empirical Analysis of a Dynamic Duopoly Model of Competition". Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 4 (1): 109–131. doi:10.1111/j.1430-9134.1995.00109.x.
- 1 2 Prasad, A.; Sethi, S. P. (2004). "Competitive Advertising under Uncertainty: Stochastic Differential Game Approach". Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications 123 (1): 163–185. doi:10.1023/B:JOTA.0000043996.62867.20.
- 1 2 Bass, F. M.; Krishamoorthy, A.; Prasad, A.; Sethi, S. P. (2005). "Generic and Brand Advertising Strategies in a Dynamic Duopoly". Marketing Science 24 (4): 556–568. doi:10.1287/mksc.1050.0119.
- 1 2 3 4 Naik, P. A.; Prasad, A.; Sethi, S. P. (2008). "Building Brand Awareness in Dynamic Oligopoly Markets". Management Science 54 (1): 129–138. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1070.0755.
- 1 2 Erickson, G. M. (2009). "An Oligopoly Model of Dynamic Advertising Competition". European Journal of Operations Research.
- ↑ Prasad, A.; Sethi, S. P. (2009). "Integrated Marketing Communications in Markets with Uncertainty and Competition". Automatica 45 (3): 601–610. doi:10.1016/j.automatica.2008.09.018.
- 1 2 3 4 Erickson, G. M. (2009). "Advertising Competition in a Dynamic Oligopoly with Multiple Brands". Operations Research 57 (5): 1106–1113. doi:10.1287/opre.1080.0663.
- 1 2 Sethi, S.P., Thompson, G.L. (2000). Optimal Control Theory: Applications to Management Science and Economics. Second Edition. Springer. ISBN 0-387-28092-8 and ISBN 0-7923-8608-6, pp. 352-355. Slides are available at http://www.utdallas.edu/~sethi/OPRE7320presentation.html
- ↑ He, X.; Prasad, A.; Sethi, S.P. (2009). "Cooperative Advertising and Pricing in a Stochastic Supply Chain: Feedback Stackelberg Strategies". Production and Operations Management 18 (1): 78–94. doi:10.1111/j.1937-5956.2009.01006.x.
- ↑ He, X.; Prasad, A.; Sethi, S.P.; Gutierrez, G. (2007). "A Survey of Stackelberg Differential Game Models in Supply and Marketing Channels". Journal of Systems Science and Systems Engineering 16 (4): 385–413. doi:10.1007/s11518-007-5058-2.
- ↑ Sethi, S.P.; Prasad, A.; He, X. (2008). "Optimal Advertising and Pricing in a New-Product Adoption Model". Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications 139 (2): 351–360. doi:10.1007/s10957-008-9472-5.
- ↑ Krishnamoorthy, A., Prasad, A., Sethi, S.P. (2009). Optimal Pricing and Advertising in a Durable-Good Duopoly. European Journal of Operations Research.