Causes of income inequality in the United States

Causes of income inequality in the United States describes why changes in the country's income distribution are occurring. This topic is subject to extensive ongoing research, media attention, and political interest, as it involves how the national income of the country is split among its people at various income levels.

Overview

U.S. inequality from 1913–2008.[1]

Income inequality in the United States has grown significantly since the early 1970s,[2][3][4][5][6][7] after several decades of stability,[8][9][10] and has been the subject of study of many scholars and institutions. The U.S. consistently exhibits higher rates of income inequality than most developed nations, arguably due to the nation's relatively enhanced support of free market capitalism.[11][12][13][14][15]

According to the CBO and others, "the precise reasons for the [recent] rapid growth in income at the top are not well understood",[16][17] but "in all likelihood," an "interaction of multiple factors" was involved.[18] "Researchers have offered several potential rationales."[16][19] Some of these rationales conflict, some overlap.[20] They include:

Paul Krugman put several of these factors into context in January 2015: "Competition from emerging-economy exports has surely been a factor depressing wages in wealthier nations, although probably not the dominant force. More important, soaring incomes at the top were achieved, in large part, by squeezing those below: by cutting wages, slashing benefits, crushing unions, and diverting a rising share of national resources to financial wheeling and dealing...Perhaps more important still, the wealthy exert a vastly disproportionate effect on policy. And elite priorities — obsessive concern with budget deficits, with the supposed need to slash social programs — have done a lot to deepen [wage stagnation and income inequality]."[26]

Market factors

Globalization

U.S. real wages remain below their 1970's peak.[27]

While economists who have studied globalization agree imports have had an effect, the timing of import growth does not match the growth of income inequality. China is the world's biggest exporter and maker of manufactured products but had a per capita income in 2007 one-seventh that of the United States. By 1995 imports of manufactured goods from low-wage countries totaled less than 3% of US gross domestic product.[28]

It wasn't until 2006 that the US imported more manufactured goods from low-wage (developing) countries than from high-wage (advanced) economies.[29] Inequality increased during the 2000–2010 decade not because of stagnating wages for less-skilled workers, but because of accelerating incomes of the top 0.1%.[28] Author Timothy Noah estimates that "trade", increases in imports are responsible for just 10% of the "Great Divergence" in income distribution.[30]

Journalist James Surowiecki notes that in the last 50 years, companies and the sectors of the economy providing the most employment in the US – major retailers, restaurant chains, and supermarkets – are ones with lower profit margins and less pricing power than in the 1960s; while sectors with high profit margins and average salaries – like high technology – have relatively few employees.[31]

Some economists claim that it is WTO-led globalization and competition from developing countries, especially China, that has resulted in the recent decline in labor’s share of income and increased unemployment in the U.S.[32] And the Economic Policy Institute and the Center for Economic and Policy Research argue that some trade agreements such as the Trans-Pacific Partnership could result in further job losses and declining wages.[33][34]

One argument contrary to the globalization/technology hypothesis relates to variation across countries. Japan, Sweden and France did not experience significant increases in income inequality during the 1979-2010 period, although the U.S. did. The top 1% income group continued to receive less than 10% of the income share in these countries, while the U.S. share rose from 10% to over 20%. Economist Emmanuel Saez wrote in 2014: "Differences across countries rule out technical change/globalization as the sole explanation...Policies play a key role in shaping inequality (tax and transfer policies, regulations, education)."[35]

Superstar hypothesis

Eric Posner and Glen Weyl point out that inequality can be predominantly explained by the superstar hypothesis. In their opinion Piketty fails to observe the accelerated turnover that is occurring in the Forbes 400; only 35 people from the original 1982 list remain today. Many have fallen off as a result of heavy spending, large-scale philanthropy, and bad investments. The current Forbes 400 is now primarily made up of newly wealthy business owners, not heirs and heiresses.[36] In parallel research, the University of Chicago’s Steven Kaplan and Stanford University’s Joshua Rauh note that 69% of those on the Forbes list are actually first generation wealth creators. That figure has risen dramatically since 1982 when it stood at 40%.[37]

Ed Dolan supports the globalization and superstar hypothesis but points out that the high earnings are based, to some extent, on moral hazard like "Bonus-based compensation schemes with inadequate clawback for losses" and the shift of losses to shareholders, unsecured creditors, or taxpayers.[38] Paul Krugman argues that for the US the surge in inequality to date is mainly due to supersalaries but capital has nonetheless been significant too. And when the current generation of the 1% turn over their wealth to their heirs these become rentiers, people who live off accumulated capital. Two decades from now America could turn into a rentier-dominated society even more unequal than Belle Époque Europe.[39]

Education

Median personal and household income according to different education levels.[40][41]

Income differences between the varying levels of educational attainment (usually measured by the highest degree of education an individual has completed) have increased. Expertise and skill certified through an academic degree translates into increased scarcity of an individual's occupational qualification which in turn leads to greater economic rewards.[42] As the United States has developed into a post-industrial society more and more employers require expertise that they did not a generation ago, while the manufacturing sector which employed many of those lacking a post-secondary education is decreasing in size.[43]

In the resulting economic job market the income discrepancy between the working class and the professional with the higher academic degrees,[44] who possess scarce amounts of certified expertise, may be growing.

Households in the upper quintiles are generally home to more, better educated and employed working income earners, than those in lower quintiles.[45] Among those in the upper quintile, 62% of householders were college graduates, 80% worked full-time and 76% of households had two or more income earners, compared to the national percentages of 27%, 58% and 42%, respectively.[44][46][47] Upper-most sphere US Census Bureau data indicated that occupational achievement and the possession of scarce skills correlates with higher income.[47]

Average earnings in 2002 for the population 18 years and over were higher at each progressively higher level of education... This relationship holds true not only for the entire population but also across most subgroups. Within each specific educational level, earnings differed by sex and race. This variation may result from a variety of factors, such as occupation, working full- or part-time, age, or labor force experience. – [44][48]

The "college premium" refers to the increase in income to workers with four-year college degrees relative to those without. The college premium doubled from 1980 to 2005, as the demand for college-educated workers has exceeded the supply. Economists Goldin and Katz estimate that the increase in economic returns to education was responsible for about 60% of the increase in wage inequality between 1973 and 2005. The supply of available graduates did not keep up with business demand due primarily to increasingly expensive college educations. Annual tuition at public and private universities averaged 4% and 20% respectively of the annual median family income from the 1950s to 1970s; by 2005 these figures were 10% and 45% as colleges raised prices in response to demand.[49] Economist David Autor wrote in 2014 that approximately two-thirds of the rise in income inequality between 1980 and 2005 was accounted for by the increased premium associated with education in general and post-secondary education in particular.[50]

Two researchers have suggested that children in low income families are exposed to 636 words an hour, as opposed to 2,153 words in high income families during the first four formative years of a child's development. This, in turn, led to low achievement in later schooling due to the inability of the low income group to verbalize concepts.[51]

A psychologist has stated that society stigmatizes poverty. Conversely, poor people tend to believe that the wealthy have been lucky or have earned their money through illegal means. She believes that both attitudes need to be discarded if the nation is to make headway in addressing the issue of inequality. She suggests that college not be a litmus test of success; that valorizing of one profession as more important than another is a problem.[52]

Skill-biased technological change

As of the mid- to late- decade of the 2000s, the most common explanation for income inequality in America was "skill-biased technological change" (SBTC) [53] – "a shift in the production technology that favors skilled over unskilled labor by increasing its relative productivity and, therefore, its relative demand".[54] For example, one scholarly colloquium on the subject that included many prominent labor economists estimated that technological change was responsible for over 40% of the increase in inequality. Other factors like international trade, decline in real minimum wage, decline in unionization and rising immigration, were each responsible for 10–15% of the increase.[55][56]

Education has a notable influence on income distribution.[57] In 2005, roughly 55% of income earners with doctorate degrees – the most educated 1.4% – were among the top 15 percent earners. Among those with Master's degrees – the most educated 10% – roughly half had incomes among the top 20 percent of earners.[40] Only among households in the top quintile were householders with college degrees in the majority.[46]

But while the higher education commonly translates into higher income,[57] and the highly educated are disproportionately represented in upper quintile households, differences in educational attainment fail to explain income discrepancies between the top 1 percent and the rest of the population. Large percentages of individuals lacking a college degree are present in all income demographics, including 33% of those with heading households with six figure incomes.[46] From 2000 to 2010, the 1.5% of Americans with an M.D., J.D., or M.B.A. and the 1.5% with a PhD saw median income gains of approximately 5%. Among those with a college or master’s degree (about 25% of the American workforce) average wages dropped by about 7%, (though this was less than the decline in wages for those who had not completed college).[58] Post-2000 data has provided "little evidence" for SBTC’s role in increasing inequality. The wage premium for college educated has risen little and there has been little shift in shares of employment to more highly skilled occupations.[59]

Approaching the issue from occupations that have been replaced or downgraded since the late 1970s, one scholar found that jobs that "require some thinking but not a lot" – or moderately skilled middle-class occupations such as cashiers, typists, welders, farmers, appliance repairmen – declined the furthest in wage rates and/or numbers. Employment requiring either more skill or less has been less affected.[60] However the timing of the great technological change of the era – internet use by business starting in the late 1990s – does not match that of the growth of income inequality (starting in the early 1970s but slackening somewhat in the 1990s). Nor does the introduction of technologies that increase the demand for more skilled workers seem to be generally associated with a divergence in household income among the population. Inventions of the 20th century such as AC electric power, the automobile, airplane, radio, television, the washing machine, Xerox machine, each had an economic impact similar to computers, microprocessors and internet, but did not coincide with greater inequality.[60]

Another explanation is that the combination of the introduction of technologies that increase the demand for skilled workers, and the failure of the American education system to provide a sufficient increase in those skilled workers has bid up those workers' salaries. An example of the slowdown in education growth in America (that began about the same time as the Great Divergence began) is the fact that the average person born in 1945 received two more years of schooling than his parents, while the average person born in 1975 received only half a year more of schooling.[30] Author Timothy Noah's "back-of-the-envelope" estimation based on "composite of my discussions with and reading of the various economists and political scientists" is that the "various failures" in America's education system are "responsible for 30%" of the post-1978 increase in inequality.[30]

Race and gender disparities

Median personal income by gender and race in 2005.

Income levels vary by gender and race with median income levels considerably below the national median for females compared to men with certain racial demographics.[61]

Despite considerable progress in pursuing gender and racial equality, some social scientists attribute these discrepancies in income partly to continued discrimination.[62]

Among women, part of the wage gap is due to employment choices and preferences. Women are more likely to consider factors other than salary when looking for employment. On average, women are less willing to travel or relocate, take more hours off and work fewer hours, and choose college majors that lead to lower paying jobs. Women are also more likely to work for governments or non-profits which pay less than the private sector.[63][64] According to this perspective certain ethnic minorities and women receive fewer promotions and opportunities for occupation and economic advancement than others. In the case of women this concept is referred to as the glass ceiling keeping women from climbing the occupational ladder.

In terms of race, Asian Americans are far more likely to be in the highest earning 5 percent than the rest of Americans.[65] Studies have shown that African Americans are less likely to be hired than White Americans with the same qualifications.[66] The continued prevalence of traditional gender roles and ethnic stereotypes may partially account for current levels of discrimination.[62] In 2005, median income levels were highest among Asian and White males and lowest among females of all races, especially those identifying as African American or Hispanic. Despite closing gender and racial gaps, considerable discrepancies remain among racial and gender demographics, even at the same level of educational attainment.[67] The economic success of Asian Americans may come from how they devote much more time to education than their peers. Asian Americans have significantly higher college graduation rates than their peers and are much more likely to enter high status and high income occupations.[68]

Median weekly earnings of full-time wage and salary workers, by sex, race, and ethnicity, 2009.[69]

Since 1953 the income gap between male and female workers has decreased considerably but remains relatively large.[70] Women currently earn significantly more Associate's, Bachelor's, and Master's degrees than men and almost as many Doctorates.[71] Women are projected to have passed men in Doctorates earned in 2006–2007, and to earn nearly two thirds of Associate's, Bachelor's, and Master's degrees by 2016.[72] Despite this, some still argue that male workers still hold higher educational attainment, as the success of women in academia is a relatively new phenomenon.[44]

Household income levels and gains for different percentiles in 2003 dollars.[73]

Though it is important to note that income inequality between sexes remained stark at all levels of educational attainment.[61] Between 1953 and 2005 median earnings as well as educational attainment increased, at a far greater pace for women than for men. Median income for female earners male earners increased 157.2% versus 36.2% for men, over four times as fast. Today the median male worker earns roughly 68.4% more than their female counterparts, compared to 176.3% in 1953. The median income of men in 2005 was 2% higher than in 1973 compared to a 74.6% increase for female earners.[70]

Racial differences remained stark as well, with the highest earning sex-gender demographic of workers aged 25 or older, Asian males (who were roughly tied with white males) earning slightly more than twice as much as the lowest-earning demographic, Hispanic females.[74][75] As mentioned above, inequality between races and gender persisted at similar education levels.[75][76] Racial differences were overall more pronounced among male than among female income earners. In 2009, Hispanics were more than twice as likely to be poor than non-Hispanic whites, research indicates.[77] Lower average English ability, low levels of educational attainment, part-time employment, the youthfulness of Hispanic household heads, and the 2007–09 recession are important factors that have pushed up the Hispanic poverty rate relative to non-Hispanic whites. During the early 1920s, median earnings decreased for both sexes, not increasing substantially until the late 1990s. Since 1974 the median income for workers of both sexes increased by 31.7% from $18,474 to $24,325, reaching its high-point in 2000.[78]

Incentives

Percent of households with 2+ income earners, and full-time workers by income.[47]

In the context of concern over income inequality, a number of economists, such as Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke, have talked about the importance of incentives: "... without the possibility of unequal outcomes tied to differences in effort and skill, the economic incentive for productive behavior would be eliminated, and our market-based economy ... would function far less effectively."[42][79]

Since abundant supply decreases market value, the possession of scarce skills considerably increases income.[44] Among the American lower class, the most common source of income was not occupation, but government welfare.[80]

Stock buybacks

Writing in the Harvard Business Review in September 2014, William Lazonick blamed record corporate stock buybacks for reduced investment in the economy and a corresponding impact on prosperity and income inequality. Between 2003 and 2012, the 449 companies in the S&P 500 used 54% of their earnings ($2.4 trillion) to buy back their own stock. An additional 37% was paid to stockholders as dividends. Together, these were 91% of profits. This left little for investment in productive capabilities or higher income for employees, shifting more income to capital rather than labor. He blamed executive compensation arrangements, which are heavily based on stock options, stock awards and bonuses for meeting earnings per share (EPS) targets (EPS increases as the number of outstanding shares decreases). Restrictions on buybacks were greatly eased in the early 1980s. He advocates changing these incentives to limit buybacks.[81]

U.S. companies are projected to increase buybacks to $701 billion in 2015 according to Goldman Sachs, an 18% increase over 2014. For scale, annual non-residential fixed investment (a proxy for business investment and a major GDP component) was estimated to be about $2.1 trillion for 2014.[82][83]

Journalist Timothy Noah wrote in 2012 that: "My own preferred hypothesis is that stockholders appropriated what once belonged to middle-class wage earners." Since the vast majority of stocks are owned by higher income households, this contributes to income inequality.[49] Journalist Harold Meyerson wrote in 2014 that: "The purpose of the modern U.S. corporation is to reward large investors and top executives with income that once was spent on expansion, research, training and employees."[84]

Tax and transfer policies

Background

Distribution of US federal taxes from 1979 to 2013, based on CBO Estimates.[85]

U.S. income inequality is comparable to other developed nations pre-tax, but is among the worst after-tax and transfers. This indicates the U.S. tax policies redistribute income from higher income to lower income households relatively less than other developed countries.[86] Journalist Timothy Noah summarized the results of several studies his 2012 book The Great Divergence:

Income taxes

A key factor in income inequality/equality is the effective rate at which income is taxed coupled with the progressivity of the tax system. A progressive tax is a tax in which the effective tax rate increases as the taxable base amount increases.[87][88][89][90][91] Overall income tax rates in the U.S. are below the OECD average, and until 2005 have been declining.[92]

How much tax policy change over the last thirty years has contributed to income inequality is disputed. In their comprehensive 2011 study of income inequality (Trends in the Distribution of Household Income Between 1979 and 2007),[93] the CBO found that,

The top fifth of the population saw a 10-percentage-point increase in their share of after-tax income. Most of that growth went to the top 1 percent of the population. All other groups saw their shares decline by 2 to 3 percentage points. In 2007, federal taxes and transfers reduced the dispersion of income by 20 percent, but that equalizing effect was larger in 1979. The share of transfer payments to the lowest-income households declined. The overall average federal tax rate fell.

However, a more recent CBO analysis indicates that with changes to 2013 tax law (e.g., the expiration of the 2001-2003 Bush tax cuts for top earners and the increased payroll taxes passed as part of the Affordable Care Act), the effective federal tax rates for the highest earning household will increase to levels not seen since 1979.[94]

According to journalist Timothy Noah, "you can't really demonstrate that U.S. tax policy had a large impact on the three-decade income inequality trend one way or the other. The inequality trend for pre-tax income during this period was much more dramatic."[95] Noah estimates tax changes account for 5% of the Great Divergence.[30]

But many – such as economist Paul Krugman – emphasize the effect of changes in taxation – such as the 2001 and 2003 Bush administration tax cuts which cut taxes far more for high-income households than those below – on increased income inequality.[96]

Part of the growth of income inequality under Republican administrations (described by Larry Bartels) has been attributed to tax policy. A study by Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez found that "large reductions in tax progressivity since the 1960s took place primarily during two periods: the Reagan presidency in the 1980s and the Bush administration in the early 2000s."[97]

During Republican President Ronald Reagan's tenure in office the top marginal income tax rate was reduced from over 70 to 28 percent, high top marginal rates like 70% being the sort in place during much of the period of great income equality following the "Great Compression".[95] The lowest marginal rate for the bottom fell from 14 to 11 percent.[98] However the effective rate on top earners before Reagan's tax cut was much lower because of loopholes and charitable contributions.[99][100]

Taxes on capital

Taxes on income derived from capital (e.g., financial assets, property and businesses) primarily affect higher income groups, who own the vast majority of capital. For example, in 2010 approximately 81% of stocks were owned by the top 10% income group and 69% by the top 5%. Only about one-third of American households have stock holdings more than $7,000. Therefore, since higher-income taxpayers have a much higher share of their income represented by capital gains, lowering taxes on capital income and gains increases after-tax income inequality.[49]

Capital gains taxes were reduced around the time income inequality began to rise again around 1980 and several times thereafter. During 1978 under President Carter, the top capital gains tax rate was reduced from 49% to 28%. President Ronald Reagan's 1981 cut in the top rate on unearned income reduced the maximum capital gains rate to only 20% – its lowest level since the Hoover administration, as part of an overall economic growth strategy. The capital gains tax rate was also reduced by President Bill Clinton in 1997, from 28% to 20%. President George W. Bush reduced the tax rate on capital gains and qualifying dividends from 20% to 15%, less than half the 35% top rate on ordinary income.[101]

CBO reported in August 1990 that: "Of the 8 studies reviewed, five, including the two CBO studies, found that cutting taxes on capital gains is not likely to increase savings, investment, or GNP much if at all." Some of the studies indicated the loss in revenue from lowering the tax rate may be offset by higher economic growth, others did not.[102]

Journalist Timothy Noah wrote in 2012 that: "Every one of these changes elevated the financial interests of business owners and stockholders above the well-being, financial or otherwise, or ordinary citizens."[49] So overall, while cutting capital gains taxes adversely affects income inequality, its economic benefits are debatable.

Other tax policies

Rising inequality has also been attributed to President Bush's veto of tax harmonization, as this would have prohibited offshore tax havens.[103]

Debate over effects of tax policies

One study[104] found reductions of total effective tax rates were most significant for individuals with highest incomes. (see "Federal Tax Rate by Income Group" chart) For those with incomes in the top 0.01 percent, overall rates of Federal tax fell from 74.6% in 1970, to 34.7% in 2004 (the reversal of the trend in 2000 with a rise to 40.8% came after the 1993 Clinton deficit reduction tax bill), the next 0.09 percent falling from 59.1% to 34.1%, before leveling off with a relatively modest drop of 41.4 to 33.0% for the 99.5–99.9 percent group. Although the tax rate for low-income earners fell as well (though not as much), these tax reductions compare with virtually no change – 23.3% tax rate in 1970, 23.4% in 2004 – for the US population overall.[104]

“We haven’t achieved the minimalist state that libertarians advocate. What we’ve achieved is a state too constrained to provide the public goods—investments in infrastructure, technology, and education—that would make for a vibrant economy and too weak to engage in the redistribution that is needed to create a fair society. But we have a state that is still large enough and distorted enough that it can provide a bounty of gifts to the wealthy.”

Joseph Stiglitz[105]

The study found the decline in progressivity since 1960 was due to the shift from allocation of corporate income taxes among labor and capital to the effects of the individual income tax.[104][106] Paul Krugman also supports this claim saying, "The overall tax rate on these high income families fell from 36.5% in 1980 to 26.7% in 1989."[107]

From the White House's own analysis, the federal tax burden for those making greater than $250,000 fell considerably during the late 1980s, 1990s and 2000s, from an effective tax of 35% in 1980, down to under 30% from the late 1980s to 2011.[108]

Many studies argue that tax changes of S corporations confound the statistics prior to 1990. However, even after these changes inflation-adjusted average after-tax income grew by 25% between 1996 and 2006 (the last year for which individual income tax data is publicly available). This average increase, however, obscures a great deal of variation. The poorest 20% of tax filers experienced a 6% reduction in income while the top 0.1 percent of tax filers saw their income almost double. Tax filers in the middle of the income distribution experienced about a 10% increase in income. Also during this period, the proportion of income from capital increased for the top 0.1 percent from 64% to 70%.[109]

Transfer payments

Transfer payments refer to payments to persons such as social security, unemployment compensation, or welfare. CBO reported in November 2014 that: "Government transfers reduce income inequality because the transfers received by lower-income households are larger relative to their market income than are the transfers received by higher-income households. Federal taxes also reduce income inequality, because the taxes paid by higher-income households are larger relative to their before-tax income than are the taxes paid by lower-income households. The equalizing effects of government transfers were significantly larger than the equalizing effects of federal taxes from 1979 to 2011.[110]

CBO also reported that less progressive tax and transfer policies have contributed to greater after-tax income inequality: "As a result of the diminishing effect of transfers and federal taxes, the Gini index for income after transfers and federal taxes grew by more than the index for market income. Between 1979 and 2007, the Gini index for market income increased by 23 percent, the index for market income after transfers increased by 29 percent, and the index for income measured after transfers and federal taxes increased by 33 percent."[110]

Other causes

Shifts in political power

Paul Krugman wrote in 2015 that: "Economists struggling to make sense of economic polarization are, increasingly, talking not about technology but about power." This market power hypothesis basically asserts that market power has concentrated in monopolies and oligopolies that enable unusual amounts of income ("rents") to be transferred from the many consumers to relatively few owners. This hypothesis is consistent with higher corporate profits without a commensurate rise in investment, as firms facing less competition choose to pass a greater share of their profits to shareholders (such as through share buybacks and dividends) rather than re-invest in the business to ward off competitors.[111]

One cause of this concentration of market power was the rightward shift in American politics toward more conservative policies since 1980, as politics plays a big role in how market power can be exercised. Policies that removed barriers to monopoly and oligopoly included anti-union laws, reduced anti-trust activity, deregulation (or failure to regulate) non-depository banking, contract laws that favored creditors over debtors, etc. Further, rising wealth concentration can be used to purchase political influence, creating a feedback loop.[111]

Decline of unions

Union membership in the United States from the Great Depression to current day. (Source: Union Membership Trends in the United States, Table A-1 Appendix A for 1930 to 2000; Bureau of Labor Statistics for 2005 and 2010.)

The era of inequality growth has coincided with a dramatic decline in labor union membership from 20% of the labor force in 1983 to about 12% in 2007.[112] Economists have traditionally thought that since the chief purpose of a union is to maximize the income of its members, a strong but not all-encompassing union movement led to increased income inequality. Given the increase in income inequality of the past few decades, either the sign of the effect must be reversed, the magnitude of the effect small, or a much larger opposing force overridden it, since unionization has decreased in that period.[113][114]

The decline in unionization in recent decades has fed the rise in incomes at the top.

2015 IMF report[115]

However, more recently, research has shown that unions' ability to reduce income disparities among members outweighed other factors and its net effect has been to reduce national income inequality.[114][116] The decline of unions has hurt this leveling effect among men, and one economist (Berkeley economist David Card) estimating about 15–20% of the "Great Divergence" among that gender is the result of declining unionization.[114][117]

According to scholars, "As organized labor's political power dissipates, economic interests in the labor market are dispersed and policy makers have fewer incentives to strengthen unions or otherwise equalize economic rewards."[118][119][120][121][122][123] Unions were a balancing force, helping ensure wages kept up with productivity and that neither executives nor shareholders were unduly rewarded. Further, societal norms placed constraints on executive pay. This changed as union power declined (the share of unionized workers fell significantly during the Great Divergence, from over 30% to around 12%) and CEO pay skyrocketed (rising from around 40 times the average workers pay in the 1970s to over 350 times in the early 2000s).[24][25] A 2015 report by the International Monetary Fund also attributes the decline of labor's share of GDP to deunionization, noting the trend "necessarily increases the income share of corporate managers’ pay and shareholder returns . . . Moreover, weaker unions can reduce workers’ influence on corporate decisions that benefit top earners, such as the size and structure of top executive compensation."[124]

Still other researchers think it is the labor movement's loss of national political power to promote equalizing "government intervention and changes in private sector behavior" has had the greatest impact on inequality in the US.[114][125] Sociologist Jake Rosenfeld of the University of Washington argues that labor unions were the primary institution fighting inequality in the United States and helped grow a multiethnic middle class, and their decline has resulted in diminishing prospects for U.S. workers and their families.[126] Timothy Noah estimates the "decline" of labor union power "responsible for 20%" of the Great Divergence.[30] While the decline of union power in the US has been a factor in declining middle class incomes,[127] they have retained their clout in Western Europe.[128] In Denmark, influential trade unions such as Fagligt Fælles Forbund (3F) ensure that fast-food workers earn a living wage, the equivalent of $20 an hour, which is more than double the hourly rate for their counterparts in the United States.[129]

Critics of technological change as an explanation for the "Great Divergence" of income levels in America[130] point to public policy and party politics, or "stuff the government did, or didn't do".[95] They argue these have led to a trend of declining labor union membership rates and resulting diminishing political clout, decreased expenditure on social services, and less government redistribution. Moreover, the United States is the only advanced economy without a labor-based political party.[131]

As of 2011, several state legislatures have launched initiatives aimed at lowering wages, labor standards, and workplace protections for both union and non-union workers.[132]

Political parties and presidents

Liberal political scientist Larry Bartels has found a strong correlation between the party of the president and income inequality in America since 1948. (see below)[133][134] Examining average annual pre-tax income growth from 1948 to 2005 (which encompassed most of the egalitarian Great Compression and the entire inegalitarian Great Divergence)[135] Bartels shows that under Democratic presidents (from Harry Truman forward), the greatest income gains have been at the bottom of the income scale and tapered off as income rose. Under Republican presidents, in contrast, gains were much less but what growth there was concentrated towards the top, tapering off as you went down the income scale.[136][137]

Summarizing Bartels's findings, journalist Timothy Noah referred to the administrations of Democratic presidents as "Democrat-world", and GOP administrations as "Republican-world":

In Democrat-world, pre-tax income increased 2.64% annually for the poor and lower-middle-class and 2.12% annually for the upper-middle-class and rich. There was no Great Divergence. Instead, the Great Compression – the egalitarian income trend that prevailed through the 1940s, 1950s, and 1960s – continued to the present, albeit with incomes converging less rapidly than before. In Republican-world, meanwhile, pre-tax income increased 0.43 percent annually for the poor and lower-middle-class and 1.90 percent for the upper-middle-class and rich. Not only did the Great Divergence occur; it was more greatly divergent. Also of note: In Democrat-world pre-tax income increased faster than in the real world not just for the 20th percentile but also for the 40th, 60th, and 80th. We were all richer and more equal! But in Republican-world, pre-tax income increased slower than in the real world not just for the 20th percentile but also for the 40th, 60th, and 80th. We were all poorer and less equal! Democrats also produced marginally faster income growth than Republicans at the 95th percentile, but the difference wasn't statistically significant.[95]

The pattern of distribution of growth appears to be the result of a whole host of policies,

including not only the distribution of taxes and benefits but also the government's stance toward unions, whether the minimum wage rises, the extent to which the government frets about inflation versus too-high interest rates, etc., etc.[136]

Noah admits the evidence of this correlation is "circumstantial rather than direct", but so is "the evidence that smoking is a leading cause of lung cancer."[95]

Non-party political action

Ratio of average compensation of CEOs and production workers, 1965–2009. Source: Economic Policy Institute. 2011. Based on data from Wall Street Journal/Mercer, Hay Group 2010.[138]

According to political scientists Jacob Hacker and Paul Pierson writing in the book Winner-Take-All Politics, the important policy shifts were brought on not by the Republican Party but by the development of a modern, efficient political system, especially lobbying, by top earners – and particularly corporate executives and the financial services industry.[139] The end of the 1970s saw a transformation of American politics away from a focus on the middle class, with new, much more effective, aggressive and well-financed lobbyists and pressure groups acting on behalf of upper income groups. Executives successfully eliminated any countervailing power or oversight of corporate managers (from private litigation, boards of directors and shareholders, the Securities and Exchange Commission or labor unions).[140]

The financial industry's success came from successfully pushing for deregulation of financial markets, allowing much more lucrative but much more risky investments from which it privatized the gains while socializing the losses with government bailouts.[141] (the two groups formed about 60% of the top 0.1 percent of earners.) All top earners were helped by deep cuts in estate and capital gains taxes, and tax rates on high levels of income.

Arguing against the proposition that the explosion in pay for corporate executives – which grew from 35X average worker pay in 1978 to over 250X average pay before the 2007 recession[142] – is driven by an increased demand for scarce talent and set according to performance, Krugman points out that multiple factors outside of executives' control govern corporate profitability, particularly in short term when the head of a company like Enron may look like a great success. Further, corporate boards follow other companies in setting pay even if the directors themselves disagree with lavish pay "partly to attract executives whom they consider adequate, partly because the financial market will be suspicious of a company whose CEO isn't lavishly paid." Finally "corporate boards, largely selected by the CEO, hire compensation experts, almost always chosen by the CEO" who naturally want to please their employers.[143]

Lucian Arye Bebchuk, Jesse M. Fried, the authors of Pay Without Performance, critique of executive pay, argue that executive capture of corporate governance is so complete that only public relations, i.e. public `outrage`, constrains their pay.[144] This in turn has been reduced as traditional critics of excessive pay – such as politicians (where need for campaign contributions from the richest outweighs populist indignation), media (lauding business genius), unions (crushed) – are now silent.[145]

In addition to politics, Krugman postulated change in norms of corporate culture have played a factor. In the 1950s and 60s, corporate executives had (or could develop) the ability to pay themselves very high compensation through control of corporate boards of directors, they restrained themselves. But by the end of the 1990s, the average real annual compensation of the top 100 C.E.O.'s skyrocketed from $1.3 million – 39 times the pay of an average worker – to $37.5 million, more than 1,000 times the pay of ordinary workers from 1982 to 2002.[21] Journalist George Packer also sees the dramatic increase in inequality in America as a product of the change in attitude of the American elite, which (in his view) has been transitioning itself from pillars of society to a special interest group.[146] Author Timothy Noah estimates that what he calls "Wall Street and corporate boards' pampering" of the highest earning 0.1% is "responsible for 30%" of the post-1978 increase in inequality.[30]

Immigration

The Immigration and Nationality Act of 1965 increased immigration to America, especially of non-Europeans.[17] From 1970 to 2007, the foreign-born proportion of America's population grew from 5% to 11%, most of whom had lower education levels and incomes than native-born Americans. But the contribution of this increase in supply of low-skill labor seem to have been relatively modest. One estimate stated that immigration reduced the average annual income of native-born "high-school dropouts" ("who roughly correspond to the poorest tenth of the workforce") by 7.4% from 1980 to 2000. The decline in income of better educated workers was much less.[17] Author Timothy Noah estimates that "immigration" is responsible for just 5% of the "Great Divergence" in income distribution,[30] as does economist David Card.[147]

While immigration was found to have slightly depressed the wages of the least skilled and least educated American workers, it doesn't explain rising inequality among high school and college graduates.[148] Scholars such as political scientists Jacob S. Hacker, Paul Pierson, Larry Bartels and Nathan Kelly, and economist Timothy Smeeding question the explanation of educational attainment and workplace skills point out that other countries with similar education levels and economies have not gone the way of the US, and that the concentration of income in the US hasn't followed a pattern of "the 29% of Americans with college degrees pulling away" from those who have less education.[11][133][149][150][151][152]

Wage theft

A September 2014 report by the Economic Policy Institute claims wage theft is also responsible for exacerbating income inequality: "Survey evidence suggests that wage theft is widespread and costs workers billions of dollars a year, a transfer from low-income employees to business owners that worsens income inequality, hurts workers and their families, and damages the sense of fairness and justice that a democracy needs to survive."[153]

Corporatism

See also: Corporatocracy
Labor's share of GDP has declined 1970 to 2013, measured based on total compensation as well as salaries & wages. This implies capital's share is increasing.

Edmund Phelps, published an analysis in 2010 theorizing that the cause of income inequality is not free market capitalism, but instead is the result of the rise of corporatism.[154] Corporatism, in his view, is the antithesis of free market capitalism. It is characterized by semi-monopolistic organizations and banks, big employer confederations, often acting with complicit state institutions in ways that discourage (or block) the natural workings of a free economy. The primary effects of corporatism are the consolidation of economic power and wealth with end results being the attrition of entrepreneurial and free market dynamism.

His follow-up book, Mass Flourishing, further defines corporatism by the following attributes: power-sharing between government and large corporations (exemplified in the U.S. by widening government power in areas such as financial services, healthcare, and energy through regulation), an expansion of corporate lobbying and campaign support in exchange for government reciprocity, escalation in the growth and influence of financial and banking sectors, increased consolidation of the corporate landscape through merger and acquisition (with ensuing increases in corporate executive compensation), increased potential for corporate/government corruption and malfeasance, and a lack of entrepreneurial and small business development leading to lethargic and stagnant economic conditions.[155][156]

Today, in the United States, virtually all of these economic conditions are being borne out. With regard to income inequality, the 2014 income analysis of University of California, Berkeley economist Emmanuel Saez confirms that relative growth of income and wealth is not occurring among small and mid-sized entrepreneurs and business owners (who generally populate the lower half of top one per-centers in income),[157] but instead only among the top .1 percent of income distribution ... whom Paul Krugman describes as "super-elites - corporate bigwigs and financial wheeler-dealers."[158][159]... who earn $2,000,000 or more every year.[160][161]

For example, measured relative to GDP, total compensation and its component wages and salaries have been declining since 1970. This indicates a shift in income from labor (persons who derive income from hourly wages and salaries) to capital (persons who derive income via ownership of businesses, land and assets).[162] Wages and salaries have fallen from approximately 51% GDP in 1970 to 43% GDP in 2013. Total compensation has fallen from approximately 58% GDP in 1970 to 53% GDP in 2013.[163] To put this in perspective, five percent of U.S. GDP was approximately $850 billion in 2013. This represents an additional $7,000 in wages and salaries for each of the 120 million U.S. households. Larry Summers estimated in 2007 that the lower 80% of families were receiving $664 billion less income than they would be with a 1979 income distribution (a period of much greater equality), or approximately $7,000 per family.[164]

Not receiving this income may have led many families to increase their debt burden, a significant factor in the 2007-2009 subprime mortgage crisis, as highly leveraged homeowners suffered a much larger reduction in their net worth during the crisis. Further, since lower income families tend to spend relatively more of their income than higher income families, shifting more of the income to wealthier families may slow economic growth.[165]

In another example, The Economist propounds that a swelling corporate financial and banking sector has caused Gini Coefficients to rise in the U.S. since 1980: "Financial services' share of GDP in America doubled to 8% between 1980 and 2000; over the same period their profits rose from about 10% to 35% of total corporate profits, before collapsing in 2007-09. Bankers are being paid more, too. In America the compensation of workers in financial services was similar to average compensation until 1980. Now it is twice that average."[166] The summary argument, considering these findings, is that if corporatism is the consolidation and sharing of economic and political power between large corporations and the state ... then a corresponding concentration of income and wealth (with resulting income inequality) is an expected by-product of such a consolidation.

Neoliberalism

Some economists, sociologists and anthropologists argue that neoliberalism, or the resurgence of 19th century theories relating to laissez-faire economic liberalism in the late 1970s, has been the significant driver of inequality.[167][15][168][169][170][171][172] Vicenç Navarro points to policies pertaining to the deregulation of labor markets, privatization of public institutions, union busting and reduction of public social expenditures as contributors to this widening disparity.[171] The privatization of public functions, for example, grows income inequality by depressing wages and eliminating benefits for middle class workers while increasing income for those at the top.[173] The deregulation of the labor market undermined unions by allowing the real value of the minimum wage to plummet, resulting in employment insecurity and widening wage and income inequality.[174] David M. Kotz, professor of economics at the University of Massachusetts Amherst, contends that neoliberalism "is based on the thorough domination of labor by capital."[175] As such, the advent of the neoliberal era has seen a sharp increase in income inequality through the decline of unionization, stagnant wages for workers and the rise of CEO supersalaries.[175] According to Emmanuel Saez:

The labor market has been creating much more inequality over the last thirty years, with the very top earners capturing a large fraction of macroeconomic productivity gains. A number of factors may help explain this increase in inequality, not only underlying technological changes but also the retreat of institutions developed during the New Deal and World War II - such as progressive tax policies, powerful unions, corporate provision of health and retirement benefits, and changing social norms regarding pay inequality.[176]

Pennsylvania State University political science professor Pamela Blackmon attributes the trends of growing poverty and income inequality to the convergence of several neoliberal policies during Ronald Reagan's presidency, including the decreased funding of education, decreases in the top marginal tax rates, and shifts in transfer programs for those in poverty.[177]

Fred L. Block and Margaret Somers, in expanding on Karl Polanyi's critique of laissez-faire theories in The Great Transformation, argue that Polanyi's analysis helps to explain why the revival of such ideas has contributed to the "persistent unemployment, widening inequality, and the severe financial crises that have stressed Western economies over the past forty years."[178] John Schmitt and Ben Zipperer of the Center for Economic and Policy Research also point to economic liberalism as one of the causes of income inequality. They note that European nations, in particular the social democracies of Northern Europe with extensive and well funded welfare states, have lower levels of income inequality and social exclusion than the United States.[179]

See also

References

  1. Chart was made using data initially published as Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez (2003), Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(1), 2003, 1-39. Data (and updates) shown at http://inequality.org/income-inequality
  2. "US Census Bureau. (2001). Historical Income Tables – Income Equality.". Archived from the original on February 8, 2007. Retrieved June 20, 2007.
  3. "Weinberg, D. H. (June 1996). A Brief Look At Postwar U.S. Income Inequality. US Census Bureau." (PDF). Retrieved June 20, 2007.
  4. "Burtless, G. (January 11, 200). Has U.S. Income Inequality Really Increased?. The Brookings Institution.". Retrieved June 20, 2007.
  5. "Johnston, D. (March 29, 2007). Income Gap Is Widening, Data Shows. The New York Times". March 29, 2007. Retrieved June 20, 2007.
  6. "Shaprio, E. (October 17, 2005). New IRS Data Show Income Inequality Is Again of The Rise. Center on Budget and Policy Priorities". Retrieved June 20, 2007.
  7. Rugaber, Christopher S.; Boak, Josh (January 27, 2014). "Wealth gap: A guide to what it is, why it matters". AP News. Retrieved January 27, 2014.
  8. Gilbert, Dennis (2002). American Class Structure in an Age of Growing Inequality. Wadsworth.
  9. Beeghley, Leonard (2004). The Structure of Social Stratification in the United States. Boston, MD: Pearson, Allyn & Bacpn.
  10. Piketty, Thomas (2014). Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Belknap Press. ISBN 067443000X "The Explosion of US Inequality after 1980": pp. 294–96.
  11. 1 2 Weeks, J. (2007). Inequality Trends in Some Developed OECD countries. In J. K. S. & J. Baudot (Ed.), Flat World, Big Gaps (159–174). New York: ZED Books (published in association with the United Nations).
  12. Income distribution and poverty – OECD. OECD
  13. "Can Domestic Policy Affect Income Distribution?" by Timothy Noah, The New Republic (March 13, 2012)
    • "Among the industrial democracies where income inequality is increasing, it's much worse in the United States than it is almost anywhere else. Among 34 nations recently surveyed by the OECD, the United States got beat only by Turkey, Mexico, and Chile. That's as measured by the Gini coefficient, and including taxes and government transfer payments." Note: inequality is higher in less economically developed countries such as Turkey, Mexico, Chile, which are also members of the OECD
  14. Maxwell Strachan (May 1, 2014). The U.S. Is Even More Unequal Than You Realized. The Huffington Post. Retrieved May 1, 2014.
  15. 1 2 Richard Wolff (October 26, 2011). How the 1% got richer, while the 99% got poorer. The Guardian. Retrieved October 6, 2014
  16. 1 2 Congressional Budget Office: Trends in the Distribution of Household Income Between 1979 and 2007. October 2011. p. xi
  17. 1 2 3 The Great Divergence By Timothy Noah
  18. Congressional Budget Office: Trends in the Distribution of Household Income Between 1979 and 2007. October 2011. p. 13
  19. "Yellen, J. L. (November 6, 2006). Speech to the Center for the Study of Democracy at the University of California, Irvine. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.". Retrieved June 20, 2007.
  20. Inequality in America. The rich, the poor and the growing gap between them June 15, 2006
  21. 1 2 3 4 Krugman, Paul (October 20, 2002). "For Richer". The New York Times.
  22. the superstar hypothesis was coined by the Chicago economist Sherwin Rosen) used the example of the passing of the hundreds of comedians that made a modest living at live shows in the borscht belt and other places in bygone days that have been replaced by a handful of superstar TV comedians.
  23. estimate by economist George Borjas, quoted in Conscience of a Liberal, p. 34
  24. 1 2 3 Krugman, Paul (2007). The Conscience of a Liberal. W.W. Norton Company, Inc. ISBN 978-0-393-06069-0.
  25. 1 2 EPI-Lawrence Mishel and Alyssa Davis-CEO Pay Continues to Rise-June 2014
  26. NYT-Paul Krugman-Twin Peaks Planet-January 1, 2015
  27. NYT-Paul Krugman-On Income Stagnation-November 12, 2014
  28. 1 2 "The United States of Inequality, Entry 7: Trade Didn't Create Inequality, and Then It Did," by Timothy Noah (September 14, 2010)
  29. "Trade and Wages, Reconsidered", by Paul Krugman (February 2008)
  30. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 "The United States of Inequality. Entry 9: How the Decline in K-12 Education Enriches College Graduates," by Timothy Noah, Slate.com (September 15, 2010)
  31. Surowiecki, James (August 12, 2013). "The Pay Is Too Damn Low". The New Yorker.
  32. Smith, Noah (January 6, 2014.). The Dark Side of Globalization: Why Seattle's 1999 Protesters Were Right. The Atlantic. Retrieved January 10, 2014.
  33. No Jobs from Trade Pacts: The Trans-Pacific Partnership Could Be Much Worse than the Over-Hyped Korea Deal. Economic Policy Institute. July 18, 2013
  34. Gains from Trade? The Net Effect of the Trans-Pacific Partnership Agreement on U.S. Wages. Center for Economic and Policy Research. September 2013
  35. Emmanuel Saez-Income and Wealth Inequality:Evidence and Policy Implications-October 2014
  36. Thomas Piketty Is Wrong: America Will Never Look Like a Jane Austen Novel, Eric Posner and Glen Weyl, New Republic, 2014
  37. It’s the Market: The Broad-Based Rise in the Return to Top Talent Steven N. Kaplan and Joshua Rauh, 2014
  38. Ed Dolan, Globalization and Inequality: Is there a Superstar Effect, and if so, What does it Mean?
  39. Why We're In A New Gilded Age, Paul Krugman, New York Review of Books, May 8, 2014
  40. 1 2 "US Census Bureau. (2006). Personal income and educational attainment". Retrieved September 24, 2006.
  41. "US Census Bureau. (2006). Educational attainment and median household income". Retrieved September 24, 2006.
  42. 1 2 Levine, Rhonda (1998). Social Class and Stratification. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield. 0-8476-8543-8.
  43. Zweig, M. (2004). The What's Class Got To Do With It? Ithica, NY: Cornell University Press.
  44. 1 2 3 4 5 "Stoops, N. (June, 2004). Educational Attainment in the United States: 2003. US Census Bureau." (PDF). Retrieved June 21, 2007.
  45. "Rector, R., & Herderman Jr., R. (August 24, 2004). Two Americas, One Rich, One Poor? Understanding Income Inequality In the United States. Heritage Foundation.". Retrieved June 20, 2007.
  46. 1 2 3 "US Census Bureau. (2006). Selected Characteristics of Households, by Total Money Income in 2005.". Retrieved June 21, 2007.
  47. 1 2 3 "US Census Bureau. (2006). Household income quintiles and top 5%.". Retrieved June 20, 2007.
  48. Nichole Stoops, US Census Bureau, August 2004
  49. 1 2 3 4 5 Noah, Timothy (2012). The Great Divergence. Bloomsbury Press. ISBN 978-1-60819-635-7.
  50. Science Magazine-David Autor-Skills, education and the rise of earnings inequality-May 2014
  51. Hart, Betty; Todd Risley (1995). The Early Catastrophe. American Federation of Teachers. ISSN 0148-432X.
  52. Creaser, Richard (January 22, 2014). "NECAP scores can illustrate achievement gap". The Chronicle (Barton, Vermont). pp. 1A, 22A–24A.
  53. Jacob S. Hacker and Paul Pierson (2011) Winner-Take-All Politics: How Washington made the rich richer – and turned its back on the middle class.
  54. Dictionary of economics online
  55. Economic Report of the President 1997 mentions "colloquium on this topic at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York" (1995?)
  56. Experts' Consensus on Earnings Inequality. Economic Report of the President 1997
  57. 1 2 "New York Times. (June 7, 2007). The Rewards of Education". The New York Times. June 9, 2007. Retrieved June 22, 2007.
  58. CNN-Travis Waldon-Only Advanced Degree Holders Saw Wage Gains in the Past Decade
  59. Bernstein, Jared (November 18, 2013). "Inequality’s Roots: Beyond Technology". New York Times. Retrieved November 22, 2013.
  60. 1 2 "The United States of Inequality, Entry 4: Did Computers Create Inequality?" by Timothy Noah, Slate (September 8, 2010)
  61. 1 2 "US Census Bureau. (2006). People 18 Years Old and Over, by Total Money Earnings in 2005, Age, Race, Hispanic Origin, and Sex.". Retrieved June 22, 2007.
  62. 1 2 Schaeffer, Richard (2005). Racial and Ethnic Groups. New York, NY: Prentice Hall. 013192897X.
  63. Lukas, Carrie (April 3, 2007). "A Bargain At 77 Cents To a Dollar". The Washington Post. Retrieved May 5, 2010.
  64. The Truth About the Pay Gap: Feminist politics and bad economics – Reason Magazine
  65. "US Census Bureau 2005 Economic survey, racial income distribution". Retrieved June 29, 2006.
  66. Hine, Darlene; William C. Hine; Stanley Harrold (2006). The African American Odyssey. Boston, MA: Pearson. 0-12-182217-3.
  67. "People 18 Years Old and Over, by Total Money Income in 2005, Work Experience in 2005, Age, Race, Hispanic Origin, and Sex.". Retrieved June 22, 2007.
  68. Asian-American Parenting and Academic Success. Miller-McCune. December 13, 2010
  69. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Highlights of Women’s Earnings in 2009. Report 1025, June 2010.
  70. 1 2 "US Census Bureau. (2006). People by Median Income and Sex: 1953 to 2005.". Archived from the original on November 2, 2007. Retrieved June 22, 2007.
  71. Historical summary of faculty, students, degrees, and finances in degree-granting institutions: Selected years, 1869–70 through 2005–06
  72. Degrees conferred by degree-granting institutions, by level of degree and sex of student: Selected years, 1869–70 through 2016–17
  73. "DeNavas, C., Proctor, B. D., Mills, R. J. (August 2004). Income, Poverty, Health Insurance Coverage in the United States: 2003" (PDF). Retrieved June 20, 2007.
  74. "US Census Bureau. (2006). Income distribution among Asian males, age 25+ according to educational attainment.". Retrieved June 22, 2007.
  75. 1 2 "US Census Bureau. (2006). Income distribution among Hispanic females, age 25+ according to educational attainment.". Retrieved June 22, 2007.
  76. "US Census Bureau. (2006). Personal income distribution among Asian males, age 25+ according to educational attainment.". Retrieved June 22, 2007.
  77. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, Trends in Poverty and Inequality among Hispanics, June 2011
  78. "US Census Bureau. (2006). People (Both Sexes Combined – All Races) by Median and Mean Income: 1974 to 2005.". Retrieved June 23, 2007.
  79. Economic Mobility: Is the American Dream Alive and Well? Isabel Sawhill & John E. Morton. February 21, 2007. Economic Mobility Project, Washington, D.C.. December 4, 2007. Archived November 2, 2014, at the Wayback Machine.
  80. Thompson, William; Joseph Hickey (2005). Society in Focus. Boston, MA: Pearson.
  81. Harvard Business Review-William Lazonick-Profits without Prosperity-September 2014
  82. BEA-GDP Press Release-Q3 2014 Advance Estimate-October 30, 2014
  83. Cox-Stock Buybacks Expected to Jump 18% in 2015-November 11, 2014
  84. Washington Post-Harold Meyerson-In Corporations, It's Owners Take All-August 26, 2014
  85. "The Distribution of Household Income and Federal Taxes, 2010". The US Congressional Budget Office (CBO). 2013-12-04. Retrieved 2014-01-06.
  86. New Yorker-John Cassidy-American Income Inequality in Six Charts-November 2013
  87. Webster (4b): increasing in rate as the base increases (a progressive tax)
  88. American Heritage (6). Increasing in rate as the taxable amount increases.
  89. Britannica Concise Encyclopedia: Tax levied at a rate that increases as the quantity subject to taxation increases.
  90. Princeton University WordNet: (n) progressive tax (any tax in which the rate increases as the amount subject to taxation increases)
  91. Sommerfeld, Ray M., Silvia A. Madeo, Kenneth E. Anderson, Betty R. Jackson (1992), Concepts of Taxation, Dryden Press: Fort Worth, TX
  92. Causes of income inequality in the United States, p. 104, at Google Books OECD Publishing, ISBN 978-92-64-04418-0, 2008, pp. 103, 104.
  93. Congressional Budget Office: Trends in the Distribution of Household Income Between 1979 and 2007. October 2011. p.20 and figure 12.
  94. "The Distribution of Household Income and Federal Taxes, 2010". The US Congressional Budget Office (CBO). December 4, 2013. Retrieved January 6, 2014.
  95. 1 2 3 4 5 Noah, Timothy. "Can We Blame Income Inequality on Republicans" in the multi-part series "The United States of Inequality." Slate, September 9, 2010.
  96. "New CBO Data Show Income Inequality Continues to Widen After-Tax-Income for Top 1 Percent Rose by $146,000 in 2004," by Aviva Aron-Dine and Arloc Sherman, Center on Budget and Policy Priorities (January 23, 2007)
  97. How Progressive is the U.S. Federal Tax System? A Historical and International Perspective Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez, p. 23
  98. Silliman, B. R. (2008). Will the next president reform the tax code? A historical examination. The CPA Journal, 78(11), 23–7. Retrieved from http://search.proquest.com
  99. "How Progressive is the U.S. Federal Tax System? A Historical and International Perspective"
  100. "What Do Tax Rates' Ups and Downs Mean for Economic Growth?" PBS NewsHour (Dec. 12, 2011.) Retrieved on 2013-07-29.
  101. Kocieniewski, David (January 18, 2012). "Since 1980s, the Kindest of Tax Cuts for the Rich". New York Times. Retrieved January 21, 2012.
  102. CBO-Effect of Lower Capital Gains Taxes on Economic Growth-August 1990
  103. Dickinson, Tom (November 9, 2011). "How the GOP Became the Party of the Rich". Rolling Stone. Retrieved January 2, 2012.
  104. 1 2 3 Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez, "How Progressive is the U.S. Federal Tax System? A Historical and International Perspective". Journal of Economic Perspectives Volume 21, Number 1 – Winter 2007
  105. Stiglitz, Joseph (June 2012). "We've been brainwashed". Salon Magazine. Retrieved November 17, 2014.
  106. "Even after exploiting all possible deductions and credits, the typical high-income taxpayer during the Great Prosperity paid a federal tax of well over 50 percent of his earnings." Clinton Administration Secretary of labor Robert Reich In his book Aftershock: The Next Economy and America's Future
  107. Krugman, Paul (1995). Peddling Prosperity: Economic Sense and Nonsense in an Age of Diminished Expectations. New York: W. W. Norton & Company. p. 155. ISBN 978-0-393-31292-8. Retrieved 3 February 2012.
  108. "FactChecking Obama’s Budget Speech". FactCheck.org. April 15, 2011. Retrieved January 4, 2011.
  109. Thomas L. Hungerford "Changes in the Distribution of Income Among Tax Filers Between 1996 and 2006: The Role of Labor Income, Capital Income, and Tax Policy." Congressional Research Service, December 29, 2011. http://taxprof.typepad.com/files/crs-1.pdf
  110. 1 2 "The Distribution of Household Income and Federal Taxes 2011". Congressional Budget Office, US Government. November 2014.
  111. 1 2 Krugman-NYT Review of Books-Challenging the Oligarchy-December 17, 2015
  112. "Union Members in 2007", US Bureau of Labor Statistics, January 25, 2008
  113. "Unions and wage inequality", by David Card, Thomas Lemieux and W. Craig Riddell, in Journal of Labor Research, Volume 25, Number 4, 519–59, doi:10.1007/s12122-004-1011-z
  114. 1 2 3 4 The United States of Inequality, Entry 6: The Great Divergence and the death of organized labor. By Timothy Noah, Slate.com, September 12, 2010
  115. Florence Jaumotte and Carolina Osorio Buitron. Power from the People. Finance & Development. March 2015, Vol. 52, No. 1.
  116. "Unionism and the Dispersion of Wages" by Richard B. Freeman, National Bureau of Economic Research, 1980
  117. "The Effect of Unions on Wage Inequality in the U.S. Labor Market", by David Card, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 54, No. 2. (January 2001), pp. 296–315.
  118. Bruce Westerna and Jake Rosenfeld, Unions, Norms, and the Rise in U.S. Wage Inequality, American Sociological Review, doi: 10.1177/0003122411414817, August 2011 vol. 76 no. 4 513-537
  119. Stiglitz, Joseph E. (2012). The price of inequality: how today's divided society endangers our future. New York: W.W. Norton & Company. ISBN 9780393088694.
  120. Stiglitz, Joseph; Greenwald, Bruce C. (2014). Creating a learning society: a new approach to growth, development, and social progress. New York: Columbia University Press. ISBN 9780231152143.
  121. Rosenfeld, Jake (2014). What Unions No Longer Do. Harvard University Press. ISBN 0674725115
  122. Kristof, Nicholas. The Cost of a Decline in Unions (February 2015). Kristof: "I disdained unions as bringing corruption, nepotism and rigid work rules to the labor market, impeding the economic growth that ultimately makes a country strong. I was wrong. The abuses are real. But, as unions wane in American life, it's also increasingly clear that they were doing a lot of good in sustaining middle class life — especially the private-sector unions that are now dwindling."   ....   Kristof: "He's right. This isn't something you often hear a columnist say, but I'll say it again: I was wrong. At least in the private sector, we should strengthen unions, not try to eviscerate them." The New York Times
  123. Greenhouse, Steven. Labor's Decline and Wage Inequality, The New York Times
  124. Michael Hiltzik (March 25, 2015). IMF agrees: Decline of union power has increased income inequality. Los Angeles Times. Retrieved March 26, 2015.
  125. Inequality and Institutions in 20th Century America Frank Levy and Peter Temin] Revised June 27, 2007
  126. Jake Rosenfeld, What Unions No Longer Do, (Harvard University Press, 2014), ISBN 0674725115
  127. David Madland and Keith Miller (September 17, 2013). Latest Census Data Underscore How Important Unions Are for the Middle Class. Center for American Progress. Retrieved September 18, 2013.
  128. Tami Luhby (November 8, 2011). Global income inequality: Where the U.S. ranks. CNNMoney Retrieved September 2, 2013.
  129. Liz Alderman and Steven Greenhouse (October 27, 2014). Living Wages, Rarity for U.S. Fast-Food Workers, Served Up in Denmark. The New York Times. Retrieved October 29, 2014.
  130. "CIA. (June 14, 2007). United States: Economy. World Factbook.". Retrieved June 20, 2007.
  131. Archer, Robin (2007). Why Is There No Labor Party in the United States? Princeton University Press. ISBN 0691149348 Causes of income inequality in the United States, p. 1, at Google Books Retrieved November 23, 2013.
  132. Gordon Lafer (October 31, 2013). The Legislative Attack on American Wages and Labor Standards, 2011–2012. Economic Policy Institute. Retrieved October 31, 2013.
  133. 1 2 Bartels, L. M. (2008). Unequal democracy: The political economy of the new gilded age. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
  134. Kelly, N.J. (2009). The Politics of Income Inequality in the United States. New York: Cambridge University Press.
  135. Unequal Democracy: The Political Economy of the New Gilded Age by Larry Bartels (Princeton University Press: 2008)
  136. 1 2 Paul Ryan: Inequality, Take Two, Timothy Noah, The New Republic, November 18, 2011
  137. Income Growth Rates 1948–2005 under Democratic presidents and under Republican presidents. Graphics by Catherine Mulbrandon
  138. More compensation heading to the very top: 1965–2009. May 16, 2011.
  139. Winner-Take-All Politics, p.7
  140. Winner-Take-All Politics, pp. 115, 219, 228
  141. Winner-Take-All Politics, p. 66
  142. More compensation heading for the very top EPI 2010
  143. Krugman, Paul, The Conscience of a Liberal, W W Norton & Company, 2007, pp. 143–44
  144. Causes of income inequality in the United States at Google Books By Lucian Arye Bebchuk, Jesse M. Fried]
  145. Krugman, The Conscience of a Liberal, 2007, p. 145
  146. "The Broken Contract", By George Packer, Foreign Affairs, November/December 2011
  147. Economist David Card-NBER Working Paper-Immigration and Inequality-2009
  148. "The United States of Inequality: Did the post-1965 immigration surge cause the Great Divergence?" by Timothy Noah (September 7, 2010)
  149. Smeeding, T. (2005). Public policy, economic inequality, and poverty: The United States in comparative perspective. Social Science Quarterly, 86, 956–983.
  150. "American politics, Democracy in America: Winner-Take-All Politics. It's a pretty good book." The Economist (September 21, 2010)
  151. Winner-Take-All Politics, p. 39, Figure 3
  152. Krugman, P. (2007). The conscience of a liberal. New York: W. W. Norton.
  153. An Epidemic of Wage Theft Is Costing Workers Hundreds of Millions of Dollars a Year. Economic Policy Institute. Retrieved June 13, 2015.
  154. Capitalism vs Corporatism - Edmund Phelps Columbia University. January 11, 2010).
  155. Phelps, Edmund (August 25, 2013). Mass Flourishing: How Grassroots Innovation Created Jobs, Challenge, and Change (1st ed.). Princeton University Press. p. 392. ISBN 0691158983.
  156. Mass Flourishing Book Review, Edward Glaeser, Wall Street Journal, October 18, 2013.
  157. The CFO Alliance Executive Compensation Survey 2013
  158. We Are The 99.9%, Paul Krugman, New York Times, November 24, 2011.
  159. How You, I, and Everyone Got The Top 1 Percent All Wrong, Derek Thompson, The Atlantic, March 30, 2014.
  160. The Distribution of US Wealth, Capital Income and Returns since 1913, Emmanuel Saez, Gabriel Zucman, March 2014
  161. Are You Rich Enough? The Terrible Tragedy of Income Inequality Among The 1%, Forbes, November 25, 2013
  162. Vox-Goodheart and Erfurth-Monetary policy and long-term trends-November 2014
  163. FRED Database-Income Measures vs GDP-Retrieved November 6, 2014
  164. Lawrence Summers-Harness Market Forces to Share Prosperity-June 24, 2007
  165. Mian, Atif and, Sufi, Amir (2014). House of Debt. University of Chicago. ISBN 978-0-226-08194-6.
  166. Unbottled Gini, The Economist, January 20, 2011.
  167. Haymes, Stephen; Vidal de Haymes, Maria; Miller, Reuben, eds. (2015). The Routledge Handbook of Poverty in the United States. London: Routledge. p. 7. ISBN 0415673445. Neoliberalism represents a reassertion of the liberal political economic beliefs of the 19th century in the contemporary era.
  168. Yvonne Roberts (July 13, 2012). The Price of Inequality by Joseph Stiglitz – review. The Guardian. Retrieved March 30, 2015.
  169. Gérard Duménil and Dominique Lévy (2004). Capital Resurgent: Roots of the Neoliberal Revolution. Harvard University Press. ISBN 0674011589
    • "The advent of economic neoliberalism in the 1980s triggered a shift in the world economy. In the three decades following World War II, now considered a golden age of capitalism, economic growth was high and income inequality decreasing. But in the mid-1970s this social compact was broken as the world economy entered the stagflation crisis, following a decline in the profitability of capital. This crisis opened a new phase of stagnating growth and wages, and unemployment. Interest rates as well as dividend flows rose, and income inequality widened."
  170. David Coburn. Income inequality, social cohesion and the health status of populations: the role of neo-liberalism. Elsevier, Volume 51, Issue 1, July 2000, pp 135–146. Retrieved October 7, 2014.
  171. 1 2 Vicente Navarro, ed. Neoliberalism, Globalization, and Inequalities: Consequences for Health and Quality of Life. Baywood Publishing Company, 2007. ISBN 0895033380 pp. 1-6.
  172. Lyon-Callo, Vincent (2004). Inequality, Poverty, and Neoliberal Governance: Activist Ethnography in the Homeless Sheltering Industry. University of Toronto Press. ISBN 1442600861. p. 14.
  173. David Moberg (6 June 2014). Privatizing Government Services Doesn’t Only Hurt Public Workers. In These Times. Retrieved 7 October 2014.
  174. Thomas I. Palley (May 5, 2004). From Keynesianism to Neoliberalism: Shifting Paradigms in Economics. Foreign Policy in Focus. Retrieved November 11, 2014.
  175. 1 2 David M Kotz, The Rise and Fall of Neoliberal Capitalism, (Harvard University Press, 2015), ISBN 0674725654. p. 43
  176. Saez, Emmanuel (September 3, 2013). "Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States". UC Berkeley. Retrieved September 18, 2014.
  177. Stephen Haymes, Maria Vidal de Haymes and Reuben Miller (eds), The Routledge Handbook of Poverty in the United States, (London: Routledge, 2015), ISBN 0415673445, p. 8.
  178. Henry Farrell (July 18, 2014). The free market is an impossible utopia. The Washington Post. Retrieved October 10, 2014; see also: Fred Block and Margaret R. Somers. The Power of Market Fundamentalism: Karl Polanyi's Critique. Harvard University Press, 2014. ISBN 0674050711
  179. Schmitt, John and Ben Zipperer (2006). "Is the U.S. a Good Model for Reducing Social Exclusion in Europe?" Center for Economic and Policy Research. Retrieved October 8, 2014.

Further reading

External links

This article is issued from Wikipedia - version of the Friday, May 06, 2016. The text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution/Share Alike but additional terms may apply for the media files.