First-price sealed-bid auction

A first-price sealed-bid auction (FPSBA) is a common type of auction. It is also known as blind auction,.[1] In this type of auction, all bidders simultaneously submit sealed bids, so that no bidder knows the bid of any other participant. The highest bidder pays the price they submitted.[2]:p2[3]

Strategic analysis

In a FPSBA, each bidder is characterized by his/her monetary valuation of the item for sale.

Suppose Alice is a bidder and her valuation is a. Then, if Alice is rational:

Alice would like to bid the smallest amount that can make her win the item, as long as this amount is less than a. For example, if there is another bidder Bob and he bids y and y<a, then Alice would like to bid y+\varepsilon (where \varepsilon is the smallest amount that can be added, e.g. one cent).

Unfortunately, Alice does not know what the other bidders are going to bid. Moreover, she does not even know the valuations of the other bidders. Hence, strategically, we have a Bayesian game - a game in which agents do not know the payoffs of the other agents.

The interesting challenge in such a game is to find a Bayesian Nash equilibrium. However, this is not easy even when there are only two bidders. The situation is simpler when the valuations of the bidders are i.i.d. random variables, i.e: there is a known prior distribution and the valuations of the bidders are all drawn from the same distribution.[4]:234–236

For example, suppose there are two bidders, Alice and Bob, whose valuations a and b are drawn from a Continuous uniform distribution over the interval [0,1]. Then, it is a Bayesian-Nash equilibrium when each bidder bids exactly half his/her value: Alice bids a/2 and Bob bids b/2.

PROOF: The proof takes the point-of-view of Alice. We assume that she knows that Bob bids f(b) = b/2, but she does not know b. We find the best response of Alice to Bob's strategy. Suppose Alice bids x. There are two cases:

All in all, Alice's expected gain is: f^{-1}(x)\cdot(a-x) = 2x(a-x). The maximum gain is attained when x=a/2.

Incentive-compatible variant

The FPSBA is not incentive-compatible even in the weak sense of Bayesian-Nash-Incentive-Compatibility (BNIC), since there is no Bayesian-Nash equilibrium in which bidders report their true value.

However, it is easy to create a variant of FPSBA which is BNIC, if the priors on the valuations are common knowledge. For example, for the case of Alice and Bob described above, the rules of the BNIC variant are:

In effect, this variant simulates the Bayesian-Nash equilibrium strategies of the players, so in the Bayesian-Nash equilibrium, both bidders bid their true value.

This example is a special case of a much more general principle: the revelation principle.

Comparison to second-price auction

The following table compares FPSBA to sealed-bid second-price auction (SPSBA):

Auction: First-price Second-price
Winner: Agent with highest bid Agent with highest bid
Winner pays: Winner's bid Second-highest bid
Loser pays: 0 0
Dominant strategy: No dominant strategy Bidding truthfully is dominant strategy[5]
Bayesian Nash equilibrium[6] Bidder i bids \frac{n-1}{n}v_i Bidder i truthfully bids v_i
Auctioneer's revenue[6] \frac{n-1}{n+1} \frac{n-1}{n+1}

The auctioneer's revenue is calculated in the example case, in which the valuations of the agents are drawn uniformly at random from [0,1]. As an example, when there are n=2 agents:

In both cases, the auctioneer's expected revenue is 1/3.

This fact that the revenue is the same is not a coincidence - it is a special case of the revenue equivalence theorem.

Comparison to other auctions

A FPSBA is distinct from the English auction in that bidders can only submit one bid each. Furthermore, as bidders cannot see the bids of other participants, they cannot adjust their own bids accordingly.[3]

An c has been argued to be strategically equivalent to the Dutch auction.[2]:p13

What are effectively FPSBA are commonly called tendering for procurement by companies and organizations, particularly for government contracts and auctions for mining leases.[3]

A Generalized first-price auction is a non-truthful auction mechanism for sponsored search (aka position auction).

References

  1. Shor, Mikhael, "blind auction" Dictionary of Game Theory Terms
  2. 1 2 Krishna, Vijay (2002), Auction Theory, San Diego, USA: Academic Press, ISBN 0-12-426297-X
  3. 1 2 3 McAfee, Dinesh Satam; McMillan, Dinesh (1987), "Auctions and Bidding" (PDF), Journal of Economic Literature (American Economic Association, published June 1987) 25 (2), pp. 699–738, JSTOR 2726107, retrieved 2008-06-25
  4. Vazirani, Vijay V.; Nisan, Noam; Roughgarden, Tim; Tardos, Éva (2007). Algorithmic Game Theory (PDF). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 0-521-87282-0.
  5. Hence a second-price auction is a truthful mechanism.
  6. 1 2 Calculated for n bidders whose valuations are drawn uniformly at random from [0,1]
This article is issued from Wikipedia - version of the Sunday, March 20, 2016. The text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution/Share Alike but additional terms may apply for the media files.